Sharecropping: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
→‎Economic theories of share tenancy: Mrs. Handley and some of her children, Walker County, Alabama, 8b35778.jpg
(25 intermediate revisions by 17 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Use of land by a tenant in return for a share of the crops produced}}
{{Short description|Use of land by a tenant in return for a share of the crops produced}}
{{Distinguish|Cropsharing}}<!-- Cleanup note: Sharecropping is often referred to in the past tense though it is an ongoing practice. Some of this may be due to US sources being used to speak to sharecropping more generally. (January 2024) -->
{{Distinguish|Cropsharing}}
{{Multiple issues|
{{Cleanup|date=January 2024|reason=tense issues.}}
{{more citations needed|date=December 2020}}
{{more citations needed|date=December 2020}}
{{Blacklisted-links|1=
{{Blacklisted-links|1=
*http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.html
*http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.html
*:''Triggered by <code>\beconlib\.org\b</code> on the local blacklist''|bot=Cyberbot II|invisible=true}}
*:''Triggered by <code>\beconlib\.org\b</code> on the local blacklist''|bot=Cyberbot II|invisible=true}}
}}
{{Agriculture|land}}
{{Agriculture|land}}


'''Sharecropping''' is a legal arrangement with regard to agricultural land in which a landowner allows a tenant to use the land in return for a share of the crops produced on that land.
'''Sharecropping''' is a legal arrangement in which a landowner allows a tenant to use the land in return for a share of the crops produced on that land.


Sharecropping has a long history and there are a wide range of different situations and types of agreements that have used a form of the system. Some are governed by tradition, and others by law. The [[Italy|Italian]] ''[[mezzadria]]'', the [[France|French]] ''[[métayage]]'', the [[Catalonia|Catalan]] ''[[masoveria]]'', the [[Castile (historical region)|Castilian]] ''mediero'', the Slavic ''połownictwo'' and ''izdolshchina'', and the [[Islamic economics|Islamic system]] of ''muzara‘a'' (المزارعة), are examples of legal systems that have supported sharecropping.
Sharecropping has a long history and there are a wide range of different situations and types of agreements that have used a form of the system. Some are governed by tradition, and others by law. The [[France|French]] ''[[métayage]]'', the [[Catalonia|Catalan]] ''[[masoveria]]'', the [[Castile (historical region)|Castilian]] ''mediero'', the [[Slavs|Slavic]] ''połownictwo'' and ''izdolshchina, the [[Italy|Italian]] mezzadria'', and the [[Islamic economics|Islamic system]] of ''muzara‘a'' (المزارعة), are examples of legal systems that have supported sharecropping.


==Overview==
==Overview==
[[File:Greene Co Ga1941 Delano.jpg|thumb|left|A [[Farm Security Administration]] photo of a cropper family chopping the weeds from cotton near [[White Plains, Georgia|White Plains]], in Georgia, US (1941)]]
[[File:Greene Co Ga1941 Delano.jpg|thumb|left|A [[Farm Security Administration]] photo of a cropper family chopping the weeds from cotton near [[White Plains, Georgia|White Plains]], in Georgia, US (1941)]]


Sharecropping has benefits and costs for both the owners and the tenant. Under a sharecropping system, the landowner provided a share of land to be worked by the sharecropper, and usually provided other necessities such as housing, tools, seed, or [[working animal]]s.<ref name=":0" /> Local merchants usually provided food and other supplies to the sharecropper on credit. In exchange for the land and supplies, the cropper would pay the owner a share of the crop at the end of the season, typically one-half to two-thirds. The cropper used his share to pay off his debt to the merchant.<ref name=":1">Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" ''The Journal of Negro History'', Vol. 62, No.1 (January 1977), pp. 60–80 [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2717191 in JSTOR]</ref> If there was any cash left over, the cropper kept it—but if his share came to less than what he owed, he remained in debt.
Under a sharecropping system, landowners provided a share of land to be worked by the sharecropper, and usually provided other necessities such as housing, tools, seed, or [[working animal]]s.<ref name=":0" /> Local merchants usually provide food and other supplies to the sharecropper on credit. In exchange for the land and supplies, the cropper would pay the owner a share of the crop at the end of the season, typically one-half to two-thirds. The cropper used his share to pay off their debt to the merchant.<ref name=":1">Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" ''The Journal of Negro History'', Vol. 62, No.1 (January 1977), pp. 60–80 [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2717191 in JSTOR]</ref> If there was any cash left over, the cropper kept it—but if their share came to less than what they owed, they remained in debt.

Farmers who farmed land belonging to others but owned their own mule and plow were called [[tenant farmer]]s; they owed the landowner a smaller share of their crops, as the landowner did not have to provide them with as much in the way of supplies.

In this system, the landowner encourages the cropper to remain on the land, solving the harvest rush problem.{{Clarify|reason=What is the "harvest rush"?|date=August 2021}} Since the cropper pays in shares or portions of his harvest, owners and croppers both share the risks and benefits of harvests being large or small and of prices being high or low. Because both parties benefit from larger harvests, tenants have an incentive to work harder and invest in better methods than, for example, in a [[slave plantation]] system. However, by dividing the working force into many individual workers, large farms do not benefit from [[economies of scale]].{{Citation needed|date=August 2021}} Though the arrangement protected sharecroppers from the negative effects of a bad crop, many sharecroppers (both white and black) remained quite poor.
{{-}}
=== Advantages ===
[[File:Sharecropper's commissary in Lake Providence, LA IMG 7383.JPG|thumb|The [[Commissary (store)|commissary]] or [[company store]] for sharecroppers at Lake Providence as it appeared in the 19th century]]

Sociologist [[Jeffery M. Paige]] made a distinction between centralized sharecropping found on cotton plantations and the decentralized sharecropping with other crops. The former is characterized by long lasting tenure. Tenants are tied to the landlord through the plantation store. This form of tenure tends to be replaced by paid salaries as markets penetrate. Decentralized sharecropping involves virtually no role for the landlord: plots are scattered, peasants manage their own labor and the landowners do not manufacture the crops. This form of tenure becomes more common when markets penetrate.<ref>Jeffery Paige, ''Agrarian Revolution'', page 373</ref>

Some economists have argued that sharecropping is not as exploitative as it is often perceived. John Heath and Hans P. Binswanger, contend that "evidence from around the world suggests that sharecropping is often a way for differently endowed enterprises to pool resources to mutual benefit, overcoming credit restraints and helping to manage risk."<ref>
{{cite book |editor-first = Ernest
|editor-last = Lutz
|last1 = Heath
|first1 = John
|last2 = Binswanger
|first2 = Hans P.
|name-list-style = amp
|title = Agriculture and the Environment: Perspectives on Sustainable Rural Development
|chapter = Chapter 3: Policy-Induced Effects of Natural Resource Degradation: The Case of Colombia
|publisher = [[The World Bank]]
|date = October 1998
|location = [[Washington, DC]]
|pages = [https://archive.org/details/agricultureenvir0000unse/page/32 32]
|chapter-url = http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2000/07/24/000094946_99030406232959/Rendered/PDF/multi0page.pdf#page=32
|access-date = 2011-04-01
|chapter-format = PDF
|isbn = 0-8213-4249-5
|url = https://archive.org/details/agricultureenvir0000unse/page/32
}}
</ref>

Sharecropping agreements can be made fairly, as a form of [[tenant farming]] or [[sharefarming]] that has a variable rental payment, paid in [[arrears]]. There are three different types of contracts.<ref>Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid, ''Sharecroppers All'' (1941); Gavin Wright, ''Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy since the Civil War'' (1986).</ref>
#Workers can rent plots of land from the owner for a certain sum and keep the whole crop.
#Workers work on the land and earn a fixed wage from the land owner but keep some of the crop.
#No money changes hands but the worker and land owner each keep a share of the crop.

It also gave sharecroppers a vested interest in the land, incentivizing hard work and care. American plantations were, however, wary of this interest, as they felt that would lead to African Americans demanding rights of partnership. Many black laborers denied the unilateral authority that landowners hoped to achieve, further complicating relations between landowners and sharecroppers.<ref name="Temple University Press">{{Cite book|jstor=j.ctt14bt3nz.9|title=The Origins of Southern Sharecropping|date=1993|publisher=Temple University Press|isbn=9781566390699|editor-last=Royce|editor-first=Edward|pages=181–222|last1=Royce|first1=Edward|chapter=The Rise of Southern Sharecropping}}</ref>

Landlords opt for sharecropping to avoid the administrative costs and [[Efficiency wage|shirking]] that occurs on plantations and [[hacienda]]s. It is preferred to cash tenancy because cash tenants take all the risks, and any [[harvest failure]] will hurt them and not the landlord. Therefore, they tend to demand lower rents than sharecroppers.<ref name="tjbyres">Sharecropping and Sharecroppers, T J Byres</ref>

Another possible benefit to sharecropping is that it enables women to have access to [[arable land]], albeit not as owners, in places where ownership rights are vested only in men.<ref>Bruce, John W.- ''Country Profiles of Land Tenure: Africa, 1996'' (Lesotho, p. 221) Research Paper No. 130, December 1998, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin-Madison accessed at [https://minds.wisconsin.edu/handle/1793/21869 UMN.edu] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20011125185519/http://agecon.lib.umn.edu/cgi-bin/pdf_view.pl?paperid=1153|date=2001-11-25}} June 19, 2006</ref>

===Disadvantages===
The practice was harmful to tenants with many cases of high interest rates, unpredictable harvests, and unscrupulous landlords and merchants often keeping tenant farm families severely indebted. The debt was often compounded year on year leaving the cropper vulnerable to intimidation and shortchanging.<ref>{{cite web|title=Sharecropping {{!}} Slavery By Another Name Bento {{!}} PBS|url=https://www.pbs.org/tpt/slavery-by-another-name/themes/sharecropping/|website=Sharecropping {{!}} Slavery By Another Name Bento {{!}} PBS}}</ref> Nevertheless, it appeared to be inevitable, with no serious alternative unless the croppers left agriculture.<ref>{{cite book|author=Rufus B. Spain|title=At Ease in Zion: Social History of Southern Baptists, 1865-1900|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=m6wfDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA130|year=1967|page=130|isbn=9780817350383}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|author=Johnny E. Williams|title=African American Religion and the Civil Rights Movement in Arkansas|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=e_F2iBzFKjMC&pg=PA73|year=2008|publisher=Univ. Press of Mississippi|page=73|isbn=9781604731866}}</ref>


A new system of credit, the [[Crop-lien system|crop lien]], became closely associated with sharecropping. Under this system, a planter or merchant extended a line of credit to the sharecropper while taking the year's crop as collateral. The sharecropper could then draw food and supplies all year long. When the crop was harvested, the planter or merchants who held the lien sold the harvest for the sharecropper and settled the debt.
A new system of credit, the [[Crop-lien system|crop lien]], became closely associated with sharecropping. Under this system, a planter or merchant extended a line of credit to the sharecropper while taking the year's crop as collateral. The sharecropper could then draw food and supplies all year long. When the crop was harvested, the planter or merchants who held the lien sold the harvest for the sharecropper and settled the debt.


Sociologist Jeffery M. Paige made a distinction between centralized sharecropping found on cotton plantations and the decentralized sharecropping with other crops. The former is characterized by long lasting tenure. Tenants are tied to the landlord through the [[plantation store]]. This form of tenure tends to be replaced by paid salaries as markets penetrate. Decentralized sharecropping involves virtually no role for the landlord: plots are scattered, peasants manage their own labor and the landowners do not manufacture the crops. This form of tenure becomes more common when markets penetrate.<ref>Jeffery Paige, ''Agrarian Revolution'', page 373</ref>
Sharecropping has more than a passing similarity to [[serfdom]] or [[indentured servant|indenture]], particularly where associated with large debts at a plantation store that effectively ties down the workers and their family to the land. It has therefore been seen as an issue of [[land reform]] in contexts such as the [[Mexican Revolution]].


Farmers who farmed land belonging to others but owned their own mule and plow were called [[tenant farmer]]s; they owed the landowner a smaller share of their crops, as the landowner did not have to provide them with as much in the way of supplies.
==Regions==

Historically, sharecropping occurred extensively in [[Scotland]], [[Ireland]] and colonial [[Africa]]. Use of the sharecropper system has also been identified in England (as the practice of "farming to halves").<ref>Griffiths, Liz ''[http://www.bahs.org.uk/RHT/RHT%20issue%206.pdf Farming to Halves: A New Perspective on an Absurd and Miserable System]'' in Rural History Today, Issue 6:2004 p.5, accessed at British Agricultural History Society, 16 February 2013.</ref> It was widely used in the [[Southern United States]] during the [[Reconstruction era of the United States|Reconstruction]] era (1865–1877) that followed the [[American Civil War]], which was economically devastating to the southern states.<ref name=":3" /> It is still used in many rural poor areas of the world today, notably in [[Pakistan]], [[India]], and [[Bangladesh]].<ref>{{Cite book|last1=Sanval|first1=Nasim|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=jbOPCwAAQBAJ&dq=sharecropping+pakistan&pg=PA4|title=Optimal groundwater management in Pakistan's Indus Water Basin|last2=Steven|first2=Helfand|date=2016-01-15|publisher=Intl Food Policy Res Inst|language=en}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Chaudhuri|first1=Ananish|last2=Maitra|first2=Pushkar|date=2000-01-01|title=Sharecropping contracts in rural India: A note|url=https://doi.org/10.1080/00472330080000071|journal=Journal of Contemporary Asia|volume=30|issue=1|pages=99–107|doi=10.1080/00472330080000071|s2cid=154416728|issn=0047-2336}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book|last=Byres|first=T. J.|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ulGQAgAAQBAJ&dq=sharecropping+bangladesh&pg=PA67|title=Sharecropping and Sharecroppers|date=2005-08-02|publisher=Routledge|isbn=978-1-135-78003-6|language=en}}</ref>
==Application by region==
Historically, sharecropping occurred extensively in [[Scotland]], [[Ireland]] and colonial [[Africa]]. Use of the sharecropper system has also been identified in England (as the practice of "farming to halves").<ref>Griffiths, Liz ''[http://www.bahs.org.uk/RHT/RHT%20issue%206.pdf Farming to Halves: A New Perspective on an Absurd and Miserable System]'' in Rural History Today, Issue 6:2004 p.5, accessed at British Agricultural History Society, 16 February 2013.</ref> It was widely used in the [[Southern United States]] during the [[Reconstruction era of the United States|Reconstruction]] era (1865–1877) that followed the [[American Civil War]], which was economically devastating to the Southern states.<ref name=":3" /> It is still used in many rural poor areas of the world today, notably in [[Pakistan]], [[India]], and [[Bangladesh]].<ref>{{Cite book|last1=Sanval|first1=Nasim|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=jbOPCwAAQBAJ&dq=sharecropping+pakistan&pg=PA4|title=Optimal groundwater management in Pakistan's Indus Water Basin|last2=Steven|first2=Helfand|date=2016-01-15|publisher=Intl Food Policy Res Inst|language=en}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Chaudhuri|first1=Ananish|last2=Maitra|first2=Pushkar|date=2000-01-01|title=Sharecropping contracts in rural India: A note|url=https://doi.org/10.1080/00472330080000071|journal=Journal of Contemporary Asia|volume=30|issue=1|pages=99–107|doi=10.1080/00472330080000071|s2cid=154416728|issn=0047-2336}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book|last=Byres|first=T. J.|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ulGQAgAAQBAJ&dq=sharecropping+bangladesh&pg=PA67|title=Sharecropping and Sharecroppers|date=2005-08-02|publisher=Routledge|isbn=978-1-135-78003-6|language=en}}</ref>


=== Africa ===
=== Africa ===
In settler colonies of colonial Africa, sharecropping was a feature of the agricultural life. White farmers, who owned most of the land, were frequently unable to work the whole of their farm for lack of capital. They, therefore, had African farmers to work the excess on a sharecropping basis. In South Africa the 1913 [[Natives' Land Act]]<ref>[http://www.sahistory.org.za/pages/chronology/thisday/1913-06-19.htm South African History Online, ''19 June 1913 – The native land act was passed''] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20101014095049/http://www.sahistory.org.za/pages/chronology/thisday/1913-06-19.htm |date=14 October 2010 }}</ref> outlawed the ownership of land by Africans in areas designated for white ownership and effectively reduced the status of most sharecroppers to [[tenant farmer]]s and then to farm laborers. In the 1960s, generous subsidies to white farmers meant that most farmers could afford to work their entire farms, and sharecropping faded out.
In settler colonies of colonial Africa, sharecropping was a feature of the agricultural life. White farmers, who owned most of the land, were frequently unable to work the whole of their farm for lack of capital. They, therefore, had African farmers to work the excess on a sharecropping basis.
In South Africa the 1913 [[Natives' Land Act]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.sahistory.org.za/dated-event/native-land-act-passed|archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20101014095049/http://www.sahistory.org.za/pages/chronology/thisday/1913-06-19.htm|url-status=dead|title=The Native Land Act is passed &#124; South African History Online|archive-date=14 October 2010|website=Sahistory.org.za|access-date=22 October 2023}}</ref> outlawed the ownership of land by Africans in areas designated for white ownership and effectively reduced the status of most sharecroppers to [[tenant farmer]]s and then to farm laborers. In the 1960s, generous subsidies to white farmers meant that most farmers could afford to work their entire farms, and sharecropping faded out.


The arrangement has reappeared in other African countries in modern times, including [[Ghana]]<ref>Leonard, R. and Longbottom, J., [http://www.iied.org/pubs/display.php?l=919&n=363&o=7411IIED&w=NR ''Land Tenure Lexicon: A glossary of terms from English and French speaking West Africa'']{{Dead link|date=December 2021 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}'' International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), London, 2000''</ref> and [[Zimbabwe]].<ref name="nyambara">{{cite web|title=Rural Landlords, Rural Tenants, and the Sharecropping Complex in Gokwe, Northwestern Zimbabwe, 1980s–2002|url=http://www.ies.wisc.edu/ltc/live/zimbabwe/sym1b.pdf|author=Pius S. Nyambara|year=2003|access-date=2006-05-18|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060326145652/http://www.ies.wisc.edu/ltc/live/zimbabwe/sym1b.pdf|archive-date=2006-03-26}}, Centre for Applied Social Sciences, University of Zimbabwe and Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin–Madison, March 2003 (200Kb PDF)</ref>
The arrangement has reappeared in other African countries in modern times, including [[Ghana]]<ref>Leonard, R. and Longbottom, J., [http://www.iied.org/pubs/display.php?l=919&n=363&o=7411IIED&w=NR ''Land Tenure Lexicon: A glossary of terms from English and French speaking West Africa'']{{Dead link|date=December 2021 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}'' International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), London, 2000''</ref> and [[Zimbabwe]].<ref name="nyambara">{{cite web|title=Rural Landlords, Rural Tenants, and the Sharecropping Complex in Gokwe, Northwestern Zimbabwe, 1980s–2002|url=http://www.ies.wisc.edu/ltc/live/zimbabwe/sym1b.pdf|author=Pius S. Nyambara|year=2003|access-date=2006-05-18|url-status=dead|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060326145652/http://www.ies.wisc.edu/ltc/live/zimbabwe/sym1b.pdf|archive-date=2006-03-26}}, Centre for Applied Social Sciences, University of Zimbabwe and Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin–Madison, March 2003 (200Kb PDF)</ref>


Economic historian [[Pius S. Nyambara]] argued that [[Eurocentrism|Eurocentric]] historiographical devices such as 'feudalism' or 'slavery' often qualified by weak prefixes like 'semi-' or 'quasi-' are not helpful in understanding the antecedents and functions of sharecropping in Africa.<ref name="nyambara" />
Economic historian Pius S. Nyambara argued that [[Eurocentrism|Eurocentric]] historiographical devices such as "feudalism" or "slavery" often qualified by weak prefixes like "semi-" or "quasi-" are not helpful in understanding the antecedents and functions of sharecropping in Africa.<ref name="nyambara" />


===United States===
===United States===
Line 81: Line 43:
Prior to the Civil War, sharecropping is known to have existed in [[Mississippi]] and is believed to have been in place in [[Tennessee]].<ref name="K12.MS.us">Charles Bolton, "[http://mshistory.k12.ms.us/index.php?s=extra&id=228 Farmers Without Land: The Plight of White Tenant Farmers and Sharecroppers] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304190417/http://mshistory.k12.ms.us/index.php?s=extra&id=228 |date=2016-03-04 }}", ''Mississippi History Now'', March 2004.</ref><ref name="TennesseeEncyclopedia.net">Robert Tracy McKenzie, "[http://tennesseeencyclopedia.net/entry.php?rec=1193 Sharecropping]", ''Tennessee Encyclopedia of History and Culture''.</ref> However, it was not until the economic upheaval caused by the [[American Civil War]] and the end of slavery during and after [[Reconstruction era of the United States|Reconstruction]] that it became widespread in the South.<ref>{{cite book|editor=Sharon Monteith|title=The Cambridge Companion to the Literature of the American South|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=DPMAXuWaArgC&pg=PA94|year=2013|publisher=Cambridge U.P.|page=94|isbn=9781107036789}}</ref><ref name=":3">Joseph D. Reid, "Sharecropping as an understandable market response: The postbellum South." ''Journal of Economic History'' (1973) 33#1 pp. 106–130. [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2117145 in JSTOR]</ref> It is theorized that sharecropping in the United States originated in the [[Natchez District]], roughly centered in [[Adams County, Mississippi]] with its county seat, [[Natchez, Mississippi|Natchez]].<ref>Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" ''The Journal of Negro History'', Vol. 62, No.1 (January, 1977), pp. 60–80 [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2717191 in JSTOR]</ref>
Prior to the Civil War, sharecropping is known to have existed in [[Mississippi]] and is believed to have been in place in [[Tennessee]].<ref name="K12.MS.us">Charles Bolton, "[http://mshistory.k12.ms.us/index.php?s=extra&id=228 Farmers Without Land: The Plight of White Tenant Farmers and Sharecroppers] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304190417/http://mshistory.k12.ms.us/index.php?s=extra&id=228 |date=2016-03-04 }}", ''Mississippi History Now'', March 2004.</ref><ref name="TennesseeEncyclopedia.net">Robert Tracy McKenzie, "[http://tennesseeencyclopedia.net/entry.php?rec=1193 Sharecropping]", ''Tennessee Encyclopedia of History and Culture''.</ref> However, it was not until the economic upheaval caused by the [[American Civil War]] and the end of slavery during and after [[Reconstruction era of the United States|Reconstruction]] that it became widespread in the South.<ref>{{cite book|editor=Sharon Monteith|title=The Cambridge Companion to the Literature of the American South|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=DPMAXuWaArgC&pg=PA94|year=2013|publisher=Cambridge U.P.|page=94|isbn=9781107036789}}</ref><ref name=":3">Joseph D. Reid, "Sharecropping as an understandable market response: The postbellum South." ''Journal of Economic History'' (1973) 33#1 pp. 106–130. [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2117145 in JSTOR]</ref> It is theorized that sharecropping in the United States originated in the [[Natchez District]], roughly centered in [[Adams County, Mississippi]] with its county seat, [[Natchez, Mississippi|Natchez]].<ref>Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" ''The Journal of Negro History'', Vol. 62, No.1 (January, 1977), pp. 60–80 [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2717191 in JSTOR]</ref>


After the war, plantations and other lands throughout the South were seized by the federal government. In January 1865, General [[William Tecumseh Sherman|William T. Sherman]] issued [[Special Field Orders No. 15]], which announced that he would temporarily grant newly freed families 40 acres of this seized land on the islands and coastal regions of [[Georgia (U.S. state)|Georgia]]. Many believed that this policy would be extended to all former slaves and their families as repayment for their treatment at the end of the war. In the summer of 1865, President [[Andrew Johnson]], as one of the first acts of Reconstruction, instead ordered all land under federal control be returned to the owners from whom it had been seized.
After the war, plantations and other lands throughout the South were seized by the federal government. In January 1865, General [[William Tecumseh Sherman|William T. Sherman]] issued [[Special Field Orders No. 15]], which announced that he would temporarily grant newly freed families 40 acres of this seized land on the islands and coastal regions of [[Georgia (U.S. state)|Georgia]]. Many believed that this policy would be extended to all formerly enslaved people and their families as repayment for their treatment at the end of the war. In the summer of 1865, President [[Andrew Johnson]], as one of the first acts of Reconstruction, instead ordered all land under federal control be returned to the owners from whom it had been seized.


[[File:Audie Murphy American Cotton Museum July 2015 05 (early 20th century Texas sharecropper's home diorama).jpg|thumb|An early 20th century [[Texas]] sharecropper's home diorama at the [[Audie Murphy American Cotton Museum]], in [[Greenville, Texas]] 2015|left]]
[[File:Audie Murphy American Cotton Museum July 2015 05 (early 20th century Texas sharecropper's home diorama).jpg|thumb|An early 20th century [[Texas]] sharecropper's home diorama at the [[Audie Murphy American Cotton Museum]], in [[Greenville, Texas]] 2015|left]]
Southern landowners thus found themselves with a great deal of land, but no liquid assets to pay for labor. Many former slaves, now called [[freedmen]], having no land or other assets of their own, needed to work to support their families. A sharecropping system centered on [[cotton]], a major [[cash crop]], developed as a result. Large plantations were subdivided into plots that could be worked by sharecroppers. Initially, sharecroppers in the American South were almost all black former slaves, but eventually cash-strapped [[Poor White|indigent white]] farmers were integrated into the system.<ref name=":1" /><ref name="Eva O 2007">Eva O'Donovan, ''Becoming Free in the Cotton South'' (2007); Gavin Wright, ''Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy Since the Civil War'' (1986); Roger L. Ransom and David Beckham, ''One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation'' (2nd ed. 2008)</ref> During Reconstruction, the federal [[Freedmen's Bureau]] ordered the arrangements for freedmen and wrote and enforced their contracts.<ref name=":2">{{cite book|author=Gregorie, Anne King|title=History of Sumter County, South Carolina, p. 274|publisher=Library Board of Sumter County|year=1954}}</ref>
Southern landowners thus found themselves with a great deal of land but no liquid assets to pay for labor. They also maintained the "belief that gangs afforded the most efficient means of labor organization", something nearly all formerly enslaved people resisted. Preferring "to organize themselves into kin groups", as well as "minimize chances for white male-black female contact by removing their female kin from work environments supervised closely by whites", black southerners were "determined to resist the old slave ways".<ref>Jones, Jaqueline. ''[https://archive.org/details/laboroflovelabor0000jone Labor of Love, Labor of Sorrow: Black Women, Work, and the Family from Slavery to the Present]''. Basic Books, 1985.</ref> Notwithstanding, many formerly enslaved people, now called [[freedmen]], having no land or other assets of their own, needed to work to support their families. A sharecropping system centered on [[cotton]], a major [[cash crop]], developed as a result. Large plantations were subdivided into plots that could be worked by sharecroppers. Initially, sharecroppers in the American South were almost all formerly enslaved black people, but eventually cash-strapped [[Poor White|indigent white]] farmers were integrated into the system.<ref name=":1" /><ref name="Eva O 2007">Eva O'Donovan, ''Becoming Free in the Cotton South'' (2007); Gavin Wright, ''Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy Since the Civil War'' (1986); Roger L. Ransom and David Beckham, ''One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation'' (2nd ed. 2008)</ref> During Reconstruction, the federal [[Freedmen's Bureau]] ordered the arrangements for freedmen and wrote and enforced their contracts.<ref name=":2">{{cite book|author=Gregorie, Anne King|title=History of Sumter County, South Carolina, p. 274|publisher=Library Board of Sumter County|year=1954}}</ref>


American sharecroppers worked a section of the plantation independently, usually growing [[cotton]], [[tobacco]], [[rice]], [[sugar]], and other [[cash crop]]s, and received half of the parcel's output.<ref>{{cite book|author=Woodman, Harold D.|title=New South – New Law: The legal foundations of credit and labor relations in the Postbellum agricultural South|publisher=Louisiana State University Press|year=1995|isbn=0-8071-1941-5|url-access=registration|url=https://archive.org/details/newsouthnewlawle0000wood}}</ref><ref>{{cite encyclopedia|url=http://www.georgiaencyclopedia.org/nge/Article.jsp?id=h-2718|title=Poor Whites|encyclopedia=The New Georgia Encyclopedia|author=F. N. Boney|access-date=2006-05-18|date=2004-02-06|archive-date=2012-08-29|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120829030116/http://www.georgiaencyclopedia.org/nge/Article.jsp?id=h-2718|url-status=dead}}</ref> Sharecroppers also often received their farming tools and all other goods from the landowner they were contracted with.<ref name=":0">Mandle, Jay R. Not Slave, Not Free: The African American Economic Experience Since the Civil War. Duke University Press, 1992, 22.</ref> Landowners dictated decisions relating to the crop mix, and sharecroppers were often in agreements to sell their portion of the crop back to the landowner, thus being subjected to manipulated prices.<ref name="Temple University Press" /> In addition to this, landowners, threatening to not renew the lease at the end of the growing season, were able to apply pressure to their tenants.<ref name="Temple University Press" /> Sharecropping often proved economically problematic, as the landowners held significant economic control.<ref>Ransom, Roger L., and Richard Sutch. ''One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation''. 2nd edition. Cambridge England ; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001, 149.</ref>
American sharecroppers worked a section of the plantation independently, usually growing [[cotton]], [[tobacco]], [[rice]], [[sugar]], and other [[cash crop]]s, and received half of the parcel's output.<ref>{{cite book|author=Woodman, Harold D.|title=New South – New Law: The legal foundations of credit and labor relations in the Postbellum agricultural South|publisher=Louisiana State University Press|year=1995|isbn=0-8071-1941-5|url-access=registration|url=https://archive.org/details/newsouthnewlawle0000wood}}</ref><ref>{{cite encyclopedia|url=http://www.georgiaencyclopedia.org/nge/Article.jsp?id=h-2718|title=Poor Whites|encyclopedia=The New Georgia Encyclopedia|author=F. N. Boney|access-date=2006-05-18|date=2004-02-06|archive-date=2012-08-29|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120829030116/http://www.georgiaencyclopedia.org/nge/Article.jsp?id=h-2718|url-status=dead}}</ref> Sharecroppers also often received their farming tools and all other goods from the landowner they were contracted with.<ref name=":0">Mandle, Jay R. Not Slave, Not Free: The African American Economic Experience Since the Civil War. Duke University Press, 1992, 22.</ref> Landowners dictated decisions relating to the crop mix, and sharecroppers were often in agreements to sell their portion of the crop back to the landowner, thus being subjected to manipulated prices.<ref name="Temple University Press">{{Cite book |last1=Royce |first1=Edward |title=The Origins of Southern Sharecropping |date=1993 |publisher=Temple University Press |isbn=9781566390699 |editor-last=Royce |editor-first=Edward |pages=181–222 |chapter=The Rise of Southern Sharecropping |jstor=j.ctt14bt3nz.9}}</ref> In addition to this, landowners, threatening to not renew the lease at the end of the growing season, were able to apply pressure to their tenants.<ref name="Temple University Press" /> Sharecropping often proved economically problematic, as the landowners held significant economic control.<ref>Ransom, Roger L., and Richard Sutch. ''One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation''. 2nd edition. Cambridge England ; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001, 149.</ref>


[[File:Frank Tengle, Bud Fields, and Floyd Burroughs, cotton sharecroppers, Hale County, Alabama.jpg|thumb|Cotton sharecroppers, [[Hale County, Alabama|Hale County]], [[Alabama]], 1936]]
[[File:Frank Tengle, Bud Fields, and Floyd Burroughs, cotton sharecroppers, Hale County, Alabama.jpg|thumb|Cotton sharecroppers, [[Hale County, Alabama|Hale County]], [[Alabama]], 1936]]
In the Reconstruction Era, sharecropping was one of few options for penniless [[freedmen]] to support themselves and their families. Other solutions included the [[crop-lien system]] (where the farmer was extended credit for seed and other supplies by the merchant), a rent labor system (where the former slave rents his land but keeps his entire crop), and the [[wage system]] (worker earns a fixed wage, but keeps none of their crop). Sharecropping was by far the most economically efficient, as it provided incentives for workers to produce a bigger harvest. It was a stage beyond simple hired labor because the sharecropper had an annual contract.<ref name=":2" /> Sharecropping as historically practiced in the American South is considered more economically productive than the [[gang system]] of slave plantations, though less efficient than modern agricultural techniques.<ref>{{cite book|author1=Larry J. Griffin|url=https://archive.org/details/isbn_9780820317298|title=The South As an American Problem|author2=Don Harrison Doyle|publisher=U. of Georgia Press|year=1995|isbn=9780820317526|page=[https://archive.org/details/isbn_9780820317298/page/168 168]|url-access=registration}}</ref>
In the Reconstruction Era, sharecropping was one of few options for penniless [[freedmen]] to support themselves and their families. Other solutions included the [[crop-lien system]] (where the farmer was extended credit for seed and other supplies by the merchant), a rent labor system (where the farmer rents the land but keeps their entire crop), and the [[wage system]] (worker earns a fixed wage but keeps none of their crop). Sharecropping as historically practiced in the American South is considered more economically productive than the [[gang system]] plantations using enslaved workers, though less productive than modern agricultural techniques.<ref name=":2" /><ref>{{cite book|author1=Larry J. Griffin|url=https://archive.org/details/isbn_9780820317298|title=The South As an American Problem|author2=Don Harrison Doyle|publisher=U. of Georgia Press|year=1995|isbn=9780820317526|page=[https://archive.org/details/isbn_9780820317298/page/168 168]|url-access=registration}}</ref>


[[File:Sharecropper's cabin, Lake Providence, LA IMG 7385.JPG|thumb|Sharecropper's cabin displayed at [[List of museums in Louisiana|Louisiana State Cotton Museum]] in [[Lake Providence, Louisiana|Lake Providence]], [[Louisiana]] (2013 photo)|left]]
[[File:Sharecropper's cabin, Lake Providence, LA IMG 7385.JPG|thumb|Sharecropper's cabin displayed at [[Louisiana State Cotton Museum]] in [[Lake Providence, Louisiana|Lake Providence]], [[Louisiana]] (2013 photo)|left]]
Sharecropping continued to be a significant institution in many states for decades following the Civil War. By the early 1930s, there were 5.5 million white tenant farmers, sharecroppers, and mixed cropping/laborers in the United States; and 3 million Blacks.<ref>The Rockabilly Legends; They Called It Rockabilly Long Before they Called It Rock and Roll by Jerry Naylor and Steve Halliday DVD</ref><ref>The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 184. {{ISBN|0-306-80743-2}}, {{ISBN|978-0-306-80743-5}}</ref> In Tennessee, sharecroppers operated approximately one-third of all farm units in the state in the 1930s, with white people making up two thirds or more of the sharecroppers.<ref name="TennesseeEncyclopedia.net" /> In Mississippi, by 1900, 36% of all white farmers were tenants or sharecroppers, while 85% of black farmers were.<ref name="K12.MS.us" />{{Dead link|date=December 2021}} In Georgia, fewer than 16,000 farms were operated by black owners in 1910, while, at the same time, African-Americans managed 106,738 farms as tenants.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.georgiaencyclopedia.org/articles/history-archaeology/sharecropping|title=Sharecropping|last=Geisen|first=James C.|date=January 26, 2007|website=New Georgia Encyclopedia|access-date=April 23, 2019}}</ref>
Sharecropping continued to be a significant institution in many states for decades following the Civil War. By the early 1930s, there were 5.5 million white tenant farmers, sharecroppers, and mixed cropping/laborers in the United States; and 3 million Blacks.<ref>The Rockabilly Legends; They Called It Rockabilly Long Before they Called It Rock and Roll by Jerry Naylor and Steve Halliday DVD</ref><ref>The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 184. {{ISBN|0-306-80743-2}}, {{ISBN|978-0-306-80743-5}}</ref> In Tennessee, sharecroppers operated approximately one-third of all farm units in the state in the 1930s, with white people making up two thirds or more of the sharecroppers.<ref name="TennesseeEncyclopedia.net" /> In Mississippi, by 1900, 36% of all white farmers were tenants or sharecroppers, while 85% of black farmers were.<ref name="K12.MS.us" /> In Georgia, fewer than 16,000 farms were operated by black owners in 1910, while, at the same time, African-Americans managed 106,738 farms as tenants.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.georgiaencyclopedia.org/articles/history-archaeology/sharecropping|title=Sharecropping|last=Geisen|first=James C.|date=January 26, 2007|website=New Georgia Encyclopedia|access-date=April 23, 2019}}</ref>


Around this time, sharecroppers began to form unions protesting against poor treatment, beginning in [[Tallapoosa County, Alabama|Tallapoosa County]], Alabama in 1931, and Arkansas in 1934. Membership in the [[Southern Tenant Farmers Union]] included both blacks and poor whites, who used meetings, protests, and [[Strike action|labor strikes]] to push for better treatment. The success of these actions frightened and enraged landlords, who responded with aggressive tactics.<ref>The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues
Around this time, sharecroppers began to form unions protesting against poor treatment, beginning in [[Tallapoosa County, Alabama|Tallapoosa County]], Alabama in 1931 and Arkansas in 1934. Membership in the [[Southern Tenant Farmers Union]] included both blacks and poor whites, who used meetings, protests, and [[Strike action|labor strikes]] to push for better treatment. The success of these actions frightened and enraged landlords, who responded with aggressive tactics.<ref>The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues
By Giles Oakley
By Giles Oakley
Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 185.
Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 185.
{{ISBN|0-306-80743-2}}, {{ISBN|978-0-306-80743-5}}
{{ISBN|0-306-80743-2}}, {{ISBN|978-0-306-80743-5}}
</ref> Landless farmers who fought the sharecropping system were socially denounced, harassed by legal and illegal means, and physically attacked by officials, landlords' agents, or in extreme cases, angry mobs.<ref>Sharecroppers All. Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid. Chapell Hill 1941. The University of North Carolina Press.</ref> Sharecroppers' strikes in Arkansas and the Missouri Bootheel, the 1939 Missouri Sharecroppers' Strike, were documented in the [[newsreel]] ''Oh Freedom After While''.<ref>[http://www.newsreel.org/nav/title.asp?tc=CN0064 California Newsreel ''Oh Freedom After While'']</ref> The plight of a sharecropper was addressed in the song ''Sharecropper's Blues'' recorded by [[Charlie Barnet]] and His Orchestra in 1944.<ref>{{cite AV media|url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=0FyKigj35Ek| archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/varchive/youtube/20211109/0FyKigj35Ek| archive-date=2021-11-09 | url-status=live|title=Charlie Barnet - Sharecropper's Blues|date=26 August 2011|work=YouTube}}{{cbignore}}</ref>[[File:Chapel for sharecroppers at Lake Providence, LA IMG 7389.JPG|thumb|Sharecroppers' chapel at Cotton Museum in Lake Providence]]The sharecropping system in the U.S. increased during the [[Great Depression]] with the creation of tenant farmers following the failure of many small farms throughout the [[Dustbowl]]. Traditional sharecropping declined after [[mechanization]] of farm work became economical beginning in the late 1930s and early 1940s.<ref name="TennesseeEncyclopedia.net" /><ref>Gordon Marshall, "[http://www.encyclopedia.com/doc/1E1-sharecro.html Sharecropping]," ''Encyclopedia.com'', 1998.</ref> As a result, many sharecroppers were forced off the farms, and migrated to cities to work in factories, or became [[migrant worker]]s in the [[Western United States]] during [[World War II]]. By the end of the 1960s, sharecropping had disappeared in the United States.
</ref> Landless farmers who fought the sharecropping system were socially denounced, harassed by legal and illegal means, and physically attacked by officials, landlords' agents, or in extreme cases, angry mobs.<ref name="All">''Sharecroppers All''. Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid. Chapell Hill 1941. The University of North Carolina Press, 2011, {{ISBN|978-0-8078-9817-8}}</ref> Sharecroppers' strikes in Arkansas and the [[Missouri Bootheel]], the 1939 Missouri Sharecroppers' Strike, were documented in the [[newsreel]] ''Oh Freedom After While''.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://newsreel.org/main.asp|title=California Newsreel - Film and Video for Social Change Since 1968|website=Newsreel.org|access-date=22 October 2023}}</ref> The plight of a sharecropper was addressed in the song ''Sharecropper's Blues'', recorded by [[Charlie Barnet|Charlie Barnet and His Orchestra]] in 1944.<ref>{{cite AV media|url=https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=0FyKigj35Ek| archive-url=https://ghostarchive.org/varchive/youtube/20211109/0FyKigj35Ek| archive-date=2021-11-09 | url-status=live|title=Charlie Barnet - Sharecropper's Blues|date=26 August 2011|work=YouTube}}{{cbignore}}</ref>[[File:Chapel for sharecroppers at Lake Providence, LA IMG 7389.JPG|thumb|Sharecroppers' chapel at Cotton Museum in Lake Providence]]The sharecropping system in the U.S. increased during the [[Great Depression]] with the creation of tenant farmers following the failure of many small farms throughout the [[Dustbowl]]. Traditional sharecropping declined after [[Mechanised agriculture|mechanization of farm work]] became economical beginning in the late 1930s and early 1940s.<ref name="TennesseeEncyclopedia.net" /><ref>Gordon Marshall, "[http://www.encyclopedia.com/doc/1E1-sharecro.html Sharecropping]," ''Encyclopedia.com'', 1998.</ref> As a result, many sharecroppers were forced off the farms, and migrated to cities to work in factories, or became [[migrant worker]]s in the [[Western United States]] during [[World War II]]. By the end of the 1960s, sharecropping had disappeared in the United States.{{citation needed|date=May 2023}}


=== Sharecropping and socioeconomic status ===
=== Sharecropping and socioeconomic status ===
About two-thirds of sharecroppers were white, the rest black. Sharecroppers, the poorest of the poor, organized for better conditions. The racially integrated [[Southern Tenant Farmers Union]] made gains for sharecroppers in the 1930s. Sharecropping had diminished in the 1940s due to the Great Depression, farm mechanization, and other factors.<ref>{{cite web |title=Sharecropping |url=https://www.pbs.org/tpt/slavery-by-another-name/themes/sharecropping/ |website=[[Slavery by Another Name#Film adaptation|Slavery by Another Name]] |publisher=[[PBS]] |access-date=7 December 2021}}</ref>
About two-thirds of sharecroppers were white, the rest black. Sharecroppers, the poorest of the poor, organized for better conditions. The racially integrated [[Southern Tenant Farmers Union]] made gains for sharecroppers in the 1930s. Sharecropping had diminished in the 1940s due to the Great Depression, farm mechanization, and other factors.<ref>{{cite web |title=Sharecropping |url=https://www.pbs.org/tpt/slavery-by-another-name/themes/sharecropping/ |website=[[Slavery by Another Name#Film adaptation|Slavery by Another Name]] |publisher=[[PBS]] |access-date=7 December 2021}}</ref>

== Impacts ==
[[File:Sharecropper's commissary in Lake Providence, LA IMG 7383.JPG|thumb|The [[Commissary (store)|commissary]] or [[company store]] for sharecroppers at [[Lake Providence, Louisiana]], as it appeared in the 19th century]]

Sharecropping was harmful to tenants with many cases of high interest rates, unpredictable harvests, and unscrupulous landlords and merchants often keeping tenant farm families severely indebted. The debt was often compounded year on year leaving the cropper vulnerable to intimidation and shortchanging.<ref>{{cite web |title=Sharecropping {{!}} Slavery By Another Name Bento {{!}} PBS |url=https://www.pbs.org/tpt/slavery-by-another-name/themes/sharecropping/ |website=Sharecropping {{!}} Slavery By Another Name Bento {{!}} PBS}}</ref> Nevertheless, it appeared to be inevitable, with no serious alternative unless the croppers left agriculture.<ref>{{cite book |author=Rufus B. Spain |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=m6wfDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA130 |title=At Ease in Zion: Social History of Southern Baptists, 1865-1900 |publisher=University of Alabama Press |year=1967 |isbn=9780817350383 |page=130}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |author=Johnny E. Williams |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=e_F2iBzFKjMC&pg=PA73 |title=African American Religion and the Civil Rights Movement in Arkansas |publisher=Univ. Press of Mississippi |year=2008 |isbn=9781604731866 |page=73}}</ref>

Landlords opt for sharecropping to avoid the administrative costs and [[Efficiency wage|shirking]] that occurs on plantations and [[hacienda]]s. It is preferred to cash tenancy because cash tenants take all the risks, and any [[harvest failure]] will hurt them and not the landlord. Therefore, they tend to demand lower rents than sharecroppers.<ref name="tjbyres">Sharecropping and Sharecroppers, T J Byres</ref>

Some economists have argued that sharecropping is not as exploitative as it is often perceived. John Heath and Hans P. Binswanger write that "evidence from around the world suggests that sharecropping is often a way for differently endowed enterprises to pool resources to mutual benefit, overcoming credit restraints and helping to manage risk."<ref>
{{cite book |last1=Heath |first1=John |url=https://archive.org/details/agricultureenvir0000unse/page/32 |title=Agriculture and the Environment: Perspectives on Sustainable Rural Development |last2=Binswanger |first2=Hans P. |date=October 1998 |publisher=[[The World Bank]] |isbn=0-8213-4249-5 |editor-last=Lutz |editor-first=Ernest |location=[[Washington, DC]] |pages=[https://archive.org/details/agricultureenvir0000unse/page/32 32] |chapter=Chapter 3: Policy-Induced Effects of Natural Resource Degradation: The Case of Colombia |access-date=2011-04-01 |chapter-url=http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2000/07/24/000094946_99030406232959/Rendered/PDF/multi0page.pdf#page=32 |chapter-format=PDF |name-list-style=amp}}
</ref>

Sharecropping agreements can be made fairly, as a form of [[tenant farming]] or [[sharefarming]] that has a variable rental payment, paid in [[arrears]]. There are three different types of contracts.<ref>Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid, ''Sharecroppers All'' (1941); Gavin Wright, ''Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy since the Civil War'' (1986).</ref>
#Workers can rent plots of land from the owner for a certain sum and keep the whole crop.
#Workers work on the land and earn a fixed wage from the land owner but keep some of the crop.
#No money changes hands but the worker and land owner each keep a share of the crop.

According to sociologist Edward Royce, "adherents of the [[Neoclassical economics|neoclassical]] approach" argued that sharecropping incentivized laborers by giving them a vested interest in the crop. American plantations were wary of this interest, as they felt that would lead to African Americans demanding rights of partnership. Many black laborers denied the unilateral authority that landowners hoped to achieve, further complicating relations between landowners and sharecroppers.<ref name="Temple University Press" />

Sharecropping may allow women to have access to [[arable land]], albeit not as owners, in places where ownership rights are vested only in men.<ref>Bruce, John W.- ''Country Profiles of Land Tenure: Africa, 1996'' (Lesotho, p. 221) Research Paper No. 130, December 1998, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin-Madison accessed at [https://minds.wisconsin.edu/handle/1793/21869 UMN.edu] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20011125185519/http://agecon.lib.umn.edu/cgi-bin/pdf_view.pl?paperid=1153|date=2001-11-25}} June 19, 2006</ref>


==Economic theories of share tenancy==
==Economic theories of share tenancy==
[[File:Farm Security Administration sharecropper photo of Mrs. Handley and some of her children in Walker County, Alabama. - NARA - 195926.tif|thumb|A sharecropper family in [[Walker County, Alabama|Walker County]], Alabama (c. 1937)]]The theory of share tenancy was long dominated by [[Alfred Marshall]]'s famous footnote in Book VI, Chapter X.14 of [[Principles of Economics (Marshall)|''Principles'']]<ref>{{cite book|author1=Alfred Marshall|title=Principles of Economics|url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.html|year=1920|edition=8th|
[[File:Mrs. Handley and some of her children, Walker County, Alabama, 8b35778.jpg | thumb|A sharecropper family in [[Walker County, Alabama|Walker County]], Alabama (c. 1937)]]The theory of share tenancy was long dominated by [[Alfred Marshall]]'s famous footnote in Book VI, Chapter X.14 of [[Principles of Economics (Marshall)|''Principles'']]<ref>{{cite book|author1=Alfred Marshall|title=Principles of Economics|url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.html|year=1920|edition=8th|
publisher=London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd}}</ref> where he illustrated the inefficiency of agricultural share-contracting. [[Steven N.S. Cheung]] (1969),<ref>{{cite journal|doi=10.1086/466658|title=Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements|journal=Journal of Law & Economics|year=1969|first=Steven N S|last=Cheung|volume=12|issue=1|pages=23–42 |s2cid=154860968|url=http://heinonline.org/HOL/LandingPage?collection=journals&handle=hein.journals/jlecono12&div=6&id=&page=|access-date=2009-06-14 }}</ref> challenged this view, showing that with sufficient competition and in the absence of transaction costs, share tenancy will be equivalent to competitive labor markets and therefore efficient.<ref>Formalized in {{cite journal|title=Sharecropping, Production Externalities and the Theory of Contracts|journal=American Journal of Agricultural Economics|year=1979|first=James |last=Roumasset|volume=61|issue=4|pages=640–647 |jstor=1239911|doi=10.2307/1239911 }}</ref>
publisher=London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd}}</ref> where he illustrated the inefficiency of agricultural share-contracting. [[Steven N.S. Cheung]] (1969),<ref>{{cite journal|doi=10.1086/466658|title=Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements|journal=Journal of Law & Economics|year=1969|first=Steven N S|last=Cheung|volume=12|issue=1|pages=23–42 |s2cid=154860968|url=http://heinonline.org/HOL/LandingPage?collection=journals&handle=hein.journals/jlecono12&div=6&id=&page=|access-date=2009-06-14 }}</ref> challenged this view, showing that with sufficient competition and in the absence of transaction costs, share tenancy will be equivalent to competitive labor markets and therefore efficient.<ref>Formalized in {{cite journal|title=Sharecropping, Production Externalities and the Theory of Contracts|journal=American Journal of Agricultural Economics|year=1979|first=James |last=Roumasset|volume=61|issue=4|pages=640–647 |jstor=1239911|doi=10.2307/1239911 }}</ref>


Line 136: Line 118:
*{{cite journal |last=Ferleger |first=Louis |title=Sharecropping Contracts in the Late-Nineteenth-Century South |journal=Agricultural History |volume=67 |issue=3 |year=1993 |pages=31–46 |jstor=3744228 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Ferleger |first=Louis |title=Sharecropping Contracts in the Late-Nineteenth-Century South |journal=Agricultural History |volume=67 |issue=3 |year=1993 |pages=31–46 |jstor=3744228 }}
*{{cite journal |last1=Garrett |first1=Martin A. |first2=Zhenhui |last2=Xu |title=The Efficiency of Sharecropping: Evidence from the Postbellum South |journal=Southern Economic Journal |volume=69 |year=2003 |issue=3 |pages=578–595 |doi=10.1002/j.2325-8012.2003.tb00514.x }}
*{{cite journal |last1=Garrett |first1=Martin A. |first2=Zhenhui |last2=Xu |title=The Efficiency of Sharecropping: Evidence from the Postbellum South |journal=Southern Economic Journal |volume=69 |year=2003 |issue=3 |pages=578–595 |doi=10.1002/j.2325-8012.2003.tb00514.x }}
*{{cite book |last=Grubbs |first=Donald H. |title=Cry from the Cotton: The Southern Tenant Farmer's Union and the New Deal |year=1971 |isbn=0-8078-1156-4 |url-access=registration |url=https://archive.org/details/cryfromcottonsou0000grub }}
*{{cite book |last=Grubbs |first=Donald H. |title=Cry from the Cotton: The Southern Tenant Farmer's Union and the New Deal |year=1971 |publisher=University of North Carolina Press |isbn=0-8078-1156-4 |url-access=registration |url=https://archive.org/details/cryfromcottonsou0000grub }}
*{{cite book |last=Hurt |first=R. Douglas Hurt |title=African American Life in the Rural South, 1900–1950 |year=2003 |isbn=0-8262-1471-1 }}
*{{cite book |last=Hurt |first=R. Douglas Hurt |title=African American Life in the Rural South, 1900–1950 |year=2003 |publisher=University of Missouri Press |isbn=0-8262-1471-1 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Liebowitz |first=Jonathan J. |title=Tenants, Sharecroppers, and the French Agricultural Depression of the Late Nineteenth Century |journal=Journal of Interdisciplinary History |volume=19 |issue=3 |year=1989 |pages=429–445 |jstor=204363 |doi=10.2307/204363 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Liebowitz |first=Jonathan J. |title=Tenants, Sharecroppers, and the French Agricultural Depression of the Late Nineteenth Century |journal=Journal of Interdisciplinary History |volume=19 |issue=3 |year=1989 |pages=429–445 |jstor=204363 |doi=10.2307/204363 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Reid |first=Joseph D. Jr. |title=Sharecropping in History and Theory |journal=Agricultural History |volume=49 |issue=2 |year=1975 |pages=426–440 |jstor=3741281 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Reid |first=Joseph D. Jr. |title=Sharecropping in History and Theory |journal=Agricultural History |volume=49 |issue=2 |year=1975 |pages=426–440 |jstor=3741281 }}
*{{cite web |last=Roll |first=Jarod |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110110173607/http://southernspaces.org/2010/out-yonder-road-working-class-self-representation-and-1939-roadside-demonstration-southeast-mis |archive-date=January 10, 2011 |url=http://southernspaces.org/2010/out-yonder-road-working-class-self-representation-and-1939-roadside-demonstration-southeast-mis |title=Out Yonder on the Road": Working Class Self-Representation and the 1939 Roadside Demonstration in Southeast Missouri |work=Southern Spaces |date=March 16, 2010 }}
*{{cite web |last=Roll |first=Jarod |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110110173607/http://southernspaces.org/2010/out-yonder-road-working-class-self-representation-and-1939-roadside-demonstration-southeast-mis |archive-date=January 10, 2011 |url=http://southernspaces.org/2010/out-yonder-road-working-class-self-representation-and-1939-roadside-demonstration-southeast-mis |title=Out Yonder on the Road": Working Class Self-Representation and the 1939 Roadside Demonstration in Southeast Missouri |work=Southern Spaces |date=March 16, 2010 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Shaban |first=R. A. |title=Testing Between Competing Models of Sharecropping |journal=Journal of Political Economy |year=1987 |volume=95 |issue=5 |pages=893–920 |doi=10.1086/261495 |s2cid=55141070 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Shaban |first=R. A. |title=Testing Between Competing Models of Sharecropping |journal=Journal of Political Economy |year=1987 |volume=95 |issue=5 |pages=893–920 |doi=10.1086/261495 |s2cid=55141070 }}
*{{cite book |last=Singh |first=N. |chapter=Theories of Sharecropping |editor-first=P. |editor-last=Bardhan |title=The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions |year=1989 |pages=33–72 |isbn=0-19-828619-8 }}
*{{cite book |last=Singh |first=N. |chapter=Theories of Sharecropping |editor-first=P. |editor-last=Bardhan |title=The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions |year=1989 |pages=33–72 |publisher=Clarendon Press |isbn=0-19-828619-8 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Southworth |first=Caleb |title=Aid to Sharecroppers: How Agrarian Class Structure and Tenant-Farmer Politics Influenced Federal Relief in the South, 1933–1935 |journal=Social Science History |volume=26 |issue=1 |year=2002 |pages=33–70 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Southworth |first=Caleb |title=Aid to Sharecroppers: How Agrarian Class Structure and Tenant-Farmer Politics Influenced Federal Relief in the South, 1933–1935 |journal=Social Science History |volume=26 |issue=1 |year=2002 |pages=33–70 }}
*{{cite journal |last=Stiglitz |first=J. |title=Incentives and Risk Sharing in Share Cropping |journal=Review of Economic Studies |year=1974 |volume=41 |issue= 2|pages=219–255 |doi= 10.2307/2296714|jstor=2296714 |url=http://cowles.yale.edu/sites/default/files/files/pub/d03/d0353.pdf }}
*{{cite journal |last=Stiglitz |first=J. |title=Incentives and Risk Sharing in Share Cropping |journal=Review of Economic Studies |year=1974 |volume=41 |issue= 2|pages=219–255 |doi= 10.2307/2296714|jstor=2296714 |url=http://cowles.yale.edu/sites/default/files/files/pub/d03/d0353.pdf }}
Line 150: Line 132:


==External links==
==External links==
{{Commonscatinline}}
*{{Commonscatinline|Sharecropping}}
* [https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Q-I5aX7qZtQ&t=102s King Cotton's Slaves], 1936 newsreel by ''[[The March of Time]]'' about landless Southern farmers
*[https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=Q-I5aX7qZtQ&t=102s King Cotton's Slaves], 1936 newsreel by ''[[The March of Time]]'' about landless Southern farmers


{{Plantation agriculture in the Southeastern United States}}
{{Plantation agriculture in the Southeastern United States}}

Revision as of 17:50, 1 April 2024

Sharecropping is a legal arrangement in which a landowner allows a tenant to use the land in return for a share of the crops produced on that land.

Sharecropping has a long history and there are a wide range of different situations and types of agreements that have used a form of the system. Some are governed by tradition, and others by law. The French métayage, the Catalan masoveria, the Castilian mediero, the Slavic połownictwo and izdolshchina, the Italian mezzadria, and the Islamic system of muzara‘a (المزارعة), are examples of legal systems that have supported sharecropping.

Overview

A Farm Security Administration photo of a cropper family chopping the weeds from cotton near White Plains, in Georgia, US (1941)

Under a sharecropping system, landowners provided a share of land to be worked by the sharecropper, and usually provided other necessities such as housing, tools, seed, or working animals.[1] Local merchants usually provide food and other supplies to the sharecropper on credit. In exchange for the land and supplies, the cropper would pay the owner a share of the crop at the end of the season, typically one-half to two-thirds. The cropper used his share to pay off their debt to the merchant.[2] If there was any cash left over, the cropper kept it—but if their share came to less than what they owed, they remained in debt.

A new system of credit, the crop lien, became closely associated with sharecropping. Under this system, a planter or merchant extended a line of credit to the sharecropper while taking the year's crop as collateral. The sharecropper could then draw food and supplies all year long. When the crop was harvested, the planter or merchants who held the lien sold the harvest for the sharecropper and settled the debt.

Sociologist Jeffery M. Paige made a distinction between centralized sharecropping found on cotton plantations and the decentralized sharecropping with other crops. The former is characterized by long lasting tenure. Tenants are tied to the landlord through the plantation store. This form of tenure tends to be replaced by paid salaries as markets penetrate. Decentralized sharecropping involves virtually no role for the landlord: plots are scattered, peasants manage their own labor and the landowners do not manufacture the crops. This form of tenure becomes more common when markets penetrate.[3]

Farmers who farmed land belonging to others but owned their own mule and plow were called tenant farmers; they owed the landowner a smaller share of their crops, as the landowner did not have to provide them with as much in the way of supplies.

Application by region

Historically, sharecropping occurred extensively in Scotland, Ireland and colonial Africa. Use of the sharecropper system has also been identified in England (as the practice of "farming to halves").[4] It was widely used in the Southern United States during the Reconstruction era (1865–1877) that followed the American Civil War, which was economically devastating to the Southern states.[5] It is still used in many rural poor areas of the world today, notably in Pakistan, India, and Bangladesh.[6][7][8]

Africa

In settler colonies of colonial Africa, sharecropping was a feature of the agricultural life. White farmers, who owned most of the land, were frequently unable to work the whole of their farm for lack of capital. They, therefore, had African farmers to work the excess on a sharecropping basis.

In South Africa the 1913 Natives' Land Act[9] outlawed the ownership of land by Africans in areas designated for white ownership and effectively reduced the status of most sharecroppers to tenant farmers and then to farm laborers. In the 1960s, generous subsidies to white farmers meant that most farmers could afford to work their entire farms, and sharecropping faded out.

The arrangement has reappeared in other African countries in modern times, including Ghana[10] and Zimbabwe.[11]

Economic historian Pius S. Nyambara argued that Eurocentric historiographical devices such as "feudalism" or "slavery" often qualified by weak prefixes like "semi-" or "quasi-" are not helpful in understanding the antecedents and functions of sharecropping in Africa.[11]

United States

Sharecroppers on the roadside after they were evicted for membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union (January 1936)

Prior to the Civil War, sharecropping is known to have existed in Mississippi and is believed to have been in place in Tennessee.[12][13] However, it was not until the economic upheaval caused by the American Civil War and the end of slavery during and after Reconstruction that it became widespread in the South.[14][5] It is theorized that sharecropping in the United States originated in the Natchez District, roughly centered in Adams County, Mississippi with its county seat, Natchez.[15]

After the war, plantations and other lands throughout the South were seized by the federal government. In January 1865, General William T. Sherman issued Special Field Orders No. 15, which announced that he would temporarily grant newly freed families 40 acres of this seized land on the islands and coastal regions of Georgia. Many believed that this policy would be extended to all formerly enslaved people and their families as repayment for their treatment at the end of the war. In the summer of 1865, President Andrew Johnson, as one of the first acts of Reconstruction, instead ordered all land under federal control be returned to the owners from whom it had been seized.

An early 20th century Texas sharecropper's home diorama at the Audie Murphy American Cotton Museum, in Greenville, Texas 2015

Southern landowners thus found themselves with a great deal of land but no liquid assets to pay for labor. They also maintained the "belief that gangs afforded the most efficient means of labor organization", something nearly all formerly enslaved people resisted. Preferring "to organize themselves into kin groups", as well as "minimize chances for white male-black female contact by removing their female kin from work environments supervised closely by whites", black southerners were "determined to resist the old slave ways".[16] Notwithstanding, many formerly enslaved people, now called freedmen, having no land or other assets of their own, needed to work to support their families. A sharecropping system centered on cotton, a major cash crop, developed as a result. Large plantations were subdivided into plots that could be worked by sharecroppers. Initially, sharecroppers in the American South were almost all formerly enslaved black people, but eventually cash-strapped indigent white farmers were integrated into the system.[2][17] During Reconstruction, the federal Freedmen's Bureau ordered the arrangements for freedmen and wrote and enforced their contracts.[18]

American sharecroppers worked a section of the plantation independently, usually growing cotton, tobacco, rice, sugar, and other cash crops, and received half of the parcel's output.[19][20] Sharecroppers also often received their farming tools and all other goods from the landowner they were contracted with.[1] Landowners dictated decisions relating to the crop mix, and sharecroppers were often in agreements to sell their portion of the crop back to the landowner, thus being subjected to manipulated prices.[21] In addition to this, landowners, threatening to not renew the lease at the end of the growing season, were able to apply pressure to their tenants.[21] Sharecropping often proved economically problematic, as the landowners held significant economic control.[22]

Cotton sharecroppers, Hale County, Alabama, 1936

In the Reconstruction Era, sharecropping was one of few options for penniless freedmen to support themselves and their families. Other solutions included the crop-lien system (where the farmer was extended credit for seed and other supplies by the merchant), a rent labor system (where the farmer rents the land but keeps their entire crop), and the wage system (worker earns a fixed wage but keeps none of their crop). Sharecropping as historically practiced in the American South is considered more economically productive than the gang system plantations using enslaved workers, though less productive than modern agricultural techniques.[18][23]

Sharecropper's cabin displayed at Louisiana State Cotton Museum in Lake Providence, Louisiana (2013 photo)

Sharecropping continued to be a significant institution in many states for decades following the Civil War. By the early 1930s, there were 5.5 million white tenant farmers, sharecroppers, and mixed cropping/laborers in the United States; and 3 million Blacks.[24][25] In Tennessee, sharecroppers operated approximately one-third of all farm units in the state in the 1930s, with white people making up two thirds or more of the sharecroppers.[13] In Mississippi, by 1900, 36% of all white farmers were tenants or sharecroppers, while 85% of black farmers were.[12] In Georgia, fewer than 16,000 farms were operated by black owners in 1910, while, at the same time, African-Americans managed 106,738 farms as tenants.[26]

Around this time, sharecroppers began to form unions protesting against poor treatment, beginning in Tallapoosa County, Alabama in 1931 and Arkansas in 1934. Membership in the Southern Tenant Farmers Union included both blacks and poor whites, who used meetings, protests, and labor strikes to push for better treatment. The success of these actions frightened and enraged landlords, who responded with aggressive tactics.[27] Landless farmers who fought the sharecropping system were socially denounced, harassed by legal and illegal means, and physically attacked by officials, landlords' agents, or in extreme cases, angry mobs.[28] Sharecroppers' strikes in Arkansas and the Missouri Bootheel, the 1939 Missouri Sharecroppers' Strike, were documented in the newsreel Oh Freedom After While.[29] The plight of a sharecropper was addressed in the song Sharecropper's Blues, recorded by Charlie Barnet and His Orchestra in 1944.[30]

Sharecroppers' chapel at Cotton Museum in Lake Providence

The sharecropping system in the U.S. increased during the Great Depression with the creation of tenant farmers following the failure of many small farms throughout the Dustbowl. Traditional sharecropping declined after mechanization of farm work became economical beginning in the late 1930s and early 1940s.[13][31] As a result, many sharecroppers were forced off the farms, and migrated to cities to work in factories, or became migrant workers in the Western United States during World War II. By the end of the 1960s, sharecropping had disappeared in the United States.[citation needed]

Sharecropping and socioeconomic status

About two-thirds of sharecroppers were white, the rest black. Sharecroppers, the poorest of the poor, organized for better conditions. The racially integrated Southern Tenant Farmers Union made gains for sharecroppers in the 1930s. Sharecropping had diminished in the 1940s due to the Great Depression, farm mechanization, and other factors.[32]

Impacts

The commissary or company store for sharecroppers at Lake Providence, Louisiana, as it appeared in the 19th century

Sharecropping was harmful to tenants with many cases of high interest rates, unpredictable harvests, and unscrupulous landlords and merchants often keeping tenant farm families severely indebted. The debt was often compounded year on year leaving the cropper vulnerable to intimidation and shortchanging.[33] Nevertheless, it appeared to be inevitable, with no serious alternative unless the croppers left agriculture.[34][35]

Landlords opt for sharecropping to avoid the administrative costs and shirking that occurs on plantations and haciendas. It is preferred to cash tenancy because cash tenants take all the risks, and any harvest failure will hurt them and not the landlord. Therefore, they tend to demand lower rents than sharecroppers.[36]

Some economists have argued that sharecropping is not as exploitative as it is often perceived. John Heath and Hans P. Binswanger write that "evidence from around the world suggests that sharecropping is often a way for differently endowed enterprises to pool resources to mutual benefit, overcoming credit restraints and helping to manage risk."[37]

Sharecropping agreements can be made fairly, as a form of tenant farming or sharefarming that has a variable rental payment, paid in arrears. There are three different types of contracts.[38]

  1. Workers can rent plots of land from the owner for a certain sum and keep the whole crop.
  2. Workers work on the land and earn a fixed wage from the land owner but keep some of the crop.
  3. No money changes hands but the worker and land owner each keep a share of the crop.

According to sociologist Edward Royce, "adherents of the neoclassical approach" argued that sharecropping incentivized laborers by giving them a vested interest in the crop. American plantations were wary of this interest, as they felt that would lead to African Americans demanding rights of partnership. Many black laborers denied the unilateral authority that landowners hoped to achieve, further complicating relations between landowners and sharecroppers.[21]

Sharecropping may allow women to have access to arable land, albeit not as owners, in places where ownership rights are vested only in men.[39]

Economic theories of share tenancy

A sharecropper family in Walker County, Alabama (c. 1937)

The theory of share tenancy was long dominated by Alfred Marshall's famous footnote in Book VI, Chapter X.14 of Principles[40] where he illustrated the inefficiency of agricultural share-contracting. Steven N.S. Cheung (1969),[41] challenged this view, showing that with sufficient competition and in the absence of transaction costs, share tenancy will be equivalent to competitive labor markets and therefore efficient.[42]

He also showed that in the presence of transaction costs, share-contracting may be preferred to either wage contracts or rent contracts—due to the mitigation of labor shirking and the provision of risk sharing. Joseph Stiglitz (1974,[43] 1988),[44] suggested that if share tenancy is only a labor contract, then it is only pairwise-efficient and that land-to-the-tiller reform would improve social efficiency by removing the necessity for labor contracts in the first place.

Reid (1973),[45] Murrel (1983),[46] Roumasset (1995)[47] and Allen and Lueck (2004)[48] provided transaction cost theories of share-contracting, wherein tenancy is more of a partnership than a labor contract and both landlord and tenant provide multiple inputs. It has also been argued that the sharecropping institution can be explained by factors such as informational asymmetry (Hallagan, 1978;[49] Allen, 1982;[50] Muthoo, 1998),[51] moral hazard (Reid, 1976;[52] Eswaran and Kotwal, 1985;[53] Ghatak and Pandey, 2000),[54] intertemporal discounting (Roy and Serfes, 2001),[55] price fluctuations (Sen, 2011)[56] or limited liability (Shetty, 1988;[57] Basu, 1992;[58] Sengupta, 1997;[59] Ray and Singh, 2001).[60]

See also

References

  1. ^ a b Mandle, Jay R. Not Slave, Not Free: The African American Economic Experience Since the Civil War. Duke University Press, 1992, 22.
  2. ^ a b Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" The Journal of Negro History, Vol. 62, No.1 (January 1977), pp. 60–80 in JSTOR
  3. ^ Jeffery Paige, Agrarian Revolution, page 373
  4. ^ Griffiths, Liz Farming to Halves: A New Perspective on an Absurd and Miserable System in Rural History Today, Issue 6:2004 p.5, accessed at British Agricultural History Society, 16 February 2013.
  5. ^ a b Joseph D. Reid, "Sharecropping as an understandable market response: The postbellum South." Journal of Economic History (1973) 33#1 pp. 106–130. in JSTOR
  6. ^ Sanval, Nasim; Steven, Helfand (2016-01-15). Optimal groundwater management in Pakistan's Indus Water Basin. Intl Food Policy Res Inst.
  7. ^ Chaudhuri, Ananish; Maitra, Pushkar (2000-01-01). "Sharecropping contracts in rural India: A note". Journal of Contemporary Asia. 30 (1): 99–107. doi:10.1080/00472330080000071. ISSN 0047-2336. S2CID 154416728.
  8. ^ Byres, T. J. (2005-08-02). Sharecropping and Sharecroppers. Routledge. ISBN 978-1-135-78003-6.
  9. ^ "The Native Land Act is passed | South African History Online". Sahistory.org.za. Archived from the original on 14 October 2010. Retrieved 22 October 2023.
  10. ^ Leonard, R. and Longbottom, J., Land Tenure Lexicon: A glossary of terms from English and French speaking West Africa[permanent dead link] International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), London, 2000
  11. ^ a b Pius S. Nyambara (2003). "Rural Landlords, Rural Tenants, and the Sharecropping Complex in Gokwe, Northwestern Zimbabwe, 1980s–2002" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2006-03-26. Retrieved 2006-05-18., Centre for Applied Social Sciences, University of Zimbabwe and Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin–Madison, March 2003 (200Kb PDF)
  12. ^ a b Charles Bolton, "Farmers Without Land: The Plight of White Tenant Farmers and Sharecroppers Archived 2016-03-04 at the Wayback Machine", Mississippi History Now, March 2004.
  13. ^ a b c Robert Tracy McKenzie, "Sharecropping", Tennessee Encyclopedia of History and Culture.
  14. ^ Sharon Monteith, ed. (2013). The Cambridge Companion to the Literature of the American South. Cambridge U.P. p. 94. ISBN 9781107036789.
  15. ^ Ronald L. F. Davis "The U. S. Army and the Origins of Sharecropping in the Natchez District—A Case Study" The Journal of Negro History, Vol. 62, No.1 (January, 1977), pp. 60–80 in JSTOR
  16. ^ Jones, Jaqueline. Labor of Love, Labor of Sorrow: Black Women, Work, and the Family from Slavery to the Present. Basic Books, 1985.
  17. ^ Eva O'Donovan, Becoming Free in the Cotton South (2007); Gavin Wright, Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy Since the Civil War (1986); Roger L. Ransom and David Beckham, One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation (2nd ed. 2008)
  18. ^ a b Gregorie, Anne King (1954). History of Sumter County, South Carolina, p. 274. Library Board of Sumter County.
  19. ^ Woodman, Harold D. (1995). New South – New Law: The legal foundations of credit and labor relations in the Postbellum agricultural South. Louisiana State University Press. ISBN 0-8071-1941-5.
  20. ^ F. N. Boney (2004-02-06). "Poor Whites". The New Georgia Encyclopedia. Archived from the original on 2012-08-29. Retrieved 2006-05-18.
  21. ^ a b c Royce, Edward (1993). "The Rise of Southern Sharecropping". In Royce, Edward (ed.). The Origins of Southern Sharecropping. Temple University Press. pp. 181–222. ISBN 9781566390699. JSTOR j.ctt14bt3nz.9.
  22. ^ Ransom, Roger L., and Richard Sutch. One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation. 2nd edition. Cambridge England ; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2001, 149.
  23. ^ Larry J. Griffin; Don Harrison Doyle (1995). The South As an American Problem. U. of Georgia Press. p. 168. ISBN 9780820317526.
  24. ^ The Rockabilly Legends; They Called It Rockabilly Long Before they Called It Rock and Roll by Jerry Naylor and Steve Halliday DVD
  25. ^ The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 184. ISBN 0-306-80743-2, ISBN 978-0-306-80743-5
  26. ^ Geisen, James C. (January 26, 2007). "Sharecropping". New Georgia Encyclopedia. Retrieved April 23, 2019.
  27. ^ The Devil's Music: A History of the Blues By Giles Oakley Edition: 2. Da Capo Press, 1997, p. 185. ISBN 0-306-80743-2, ISBN 978-0-306-80743-5
  28. ^ Sharecroppers All. Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid. Chapell Hill 1941. The University of North Carolina Press, 2011, ISBN 978-0-8078-9817-8
  29. ^ "California Newsreel - Film and Video for Social Change Since 1968". Newsreel.org. Retrieved 22 October 2023.
  30. ^ Charlie Barnet - Sharecropper's Blues. YouTube. 26 August 2011. Archived from the original on 2021-11-09.
  31. ^ Gordon Marshall, "Sharecropping," Encyclopedia.com, 1998.
  32. ^ "Sharecropping". Slavery by Another Name. PBS. Retrieved 7 December 2021.
  33. ^ "Sharecropping | Slavery By Another Name Bento | PBS". Sharecropping | Slavery By Another Name Bento | PBS.
  34. ^ Rufus B. Spain (1967). At Ease in Zion: Social History of Southern Baptists, 1865-1900. University of Alabama Press. p. 130. ISBN 9780817350383.
  35. ^ Johnny E. Williams (2008). African American Religion and the Civil Rights Movement in Arkansas. Univ. Press of Mississippi. p. 73. ISBN 9781604731866.
  36. ^ Sharecropping and Sharecroppers, T J Byres
  37. ^ Heath, John & Binswanger, Hans P. (October 1998). "Chapter 3: Policy-Induced Effects of Natural Resource Degradation: The Case of Colombia" (PDF). In Lutz, Ernest (ed.). Agriculture and the Environment: Perspectives on Sustainable Rural Development. Washington, DC: The World Bank. pp. 32. ISBN 0-8213-4249-5. Retrieved 2011-04-01.
  38. ^ Arthur F. Raper and Ira De A. Reid, Sharecroppers All (1941); Gavin Wright, Old South, New South: Revolutions in the Southern Economy since the Civil War (1986).
  39. ^ Bruce, John W.- Country Profiles of Land Tenure: Africa, 1996 (Lesotho, p. 221) Research Paper No. 130, December 1998, Land Tenure Center, University of Wisconsin-Madison accessed at UMN.edu Archived 2001-11-25 at the Wayback Machine June 19, 2006
  40. ^ Alfred Marshall (1920). Principles of Economics (8th ed.). London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd.
  41. ^ Cheung, Steven N S (1969). "Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements". Journal of Law & Economics. 12 (1): 23–42. doi:10.1086/466658. S2CID 154860968. Retrieved 2009-06-14.
  42. ^ Formalized in Roumasset, James (1979). "Sharecropping, Production Externalities and the Theory of Contracts". American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 61 (4): 640–647. doi:10.2307/1239911. JSTOR 1239911.
  43. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (1974). "Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping" (PDF). The Review of Economic Studies. 41 (2): 219–255 j. doi:10.2307/2296714. JSTOR 2296714.
  44. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph (1988). "Principal And Agent". Princeton, Woodrow Wilson School – Discussion Paper (12). Retrieved 2009-06-14.
  45. ^ Reid, Joseph D. Jr. (March 1973). "Sharecropping As An Understandable Market Response: The Post-Bellum South". The Journal of Economic History. 33 (1): 106–130. doi:10.1017/S0022050700076476. JSTOR 2117145. S2CID 155056632.
  46. ^ Murrell, Peter (Spring 1983). "The Economics of Sharing: A Transactions Cost Analysis of Contractual Choice in Farming". The Bell Journal of Economics. 14 (1): 283–293. doi:10.2307/3003555. JSTOR 3003555.
  47. ^ Roumasset, James (March 1995). "The nature of the agricultural firm". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 26 (2): 161–177. doi:10.1016/0167-2681(94)00007-2.
  48. ^ Allen, Douglas W.; Dean Lueck (2004). The Nature of the Farm: Contracts, Risk, and Organization in Agriculture. MIT Press. p. 258. ISBN 9780262511858.
  49. ^ Hallagan, William (1978). "Self-selection by contractual choice and the theory of sharecropping". Bell Journal of Economics. 9 (2): 344–354. doi:10.2307/3003586. JSTOR 3003586.
  50. ^ Allen, Franklin (1982). "On share contracts and screening". Bell Journal of Economics. 13 (2): 541–547. doi:10.2307/3003473. JSTOR 3003473.
  51. ^ Muthoo, Abhinay (1998). "Renegotiation-proof tenurial contracts as screening mechanisms". Journal of Development Economics. 56: 1–26. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(98)00050-9.
  52. ^ Reid, Joseph D. Jr. (1976). "Sharecropping and agricultural uncertainty". Economic Development and Cultural Change. 24 (3): 549–576. doi:10.1086/450897. JSTOR 1153005. S2CID 154402121.
  53. ^ Eswaran, Mukesh; Ashok Kotwal (1985). "A theory of contractual structure in agriculture". American Economic Review. 75 (3): 352–367. JSTOR 1814805.
  54. ^ Ghatak, Maitreesh; Priyanka Pandey (2000). "Contract choice in agriculture with joint moral hazard in effort and risk". Journal of Development Economics. 63 (2): 303–326. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(00)00116-4.
  55. ^ Roy, Jaideep; Konstantinos Serfes (2001). "Intertemporal discounting and tenurial contracts". Journal of Development Economics. 64 (2): 417–436. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(00)00144-9.
  56. ^ Sen, Debapriya (2011). "A theory of sharecropping: the role of price behavior and imperfect competition" (PDF). Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 80 (1): 181–199. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2011.03.006. S2CID 191253.
  57. ^ Shetty, Sudhir (1988). "Limited liability, wealth differences, and the tenancy ladder in agrarian economies". Journal of Development Economics. 29: 1–22. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(88)90068-5.
  58. ^ Basu, Kaushik (1992). "Limited liability and the existence of share tenancy" (PDF). Journal of Development Economics. 38: 203–220. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(92)90026-6.
  59. ^ Sengupta, Kunal (1997). "Limited liability, moral hazard and share tenancy". Journal of Development Economics. 52 (2): 393–407. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(96)00444-0.
  60. ^ Ray, Tridip; Nirvikar Singh (2001). "Limited liability, contractual choice and the tenancy ladder". Journal of Development Economics. 66: 289–303. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(01)00163-8.

Further reading

External links