Inflation risk premia and the expectations hypothesis

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.07.003Get rights and content

Abstract

We study the properties of the nominal and real risk premia of the term structure of interest rates. We develop and solve the bond pricing implications of a structural monetary version of a real business cycle model, with taxes and endogenous monetary policy. We show the relation of this model with the class of essentially affine models that incorporate an endogenous state-dependent market price of risk. We characterize and estimate the inflation risk premium and find that over the last 40 years the ten-year inflation risk premium has been has averaged 70 basis points. It is time-varying, ranging from 20 to 140 basis points over the business cycle and its term structure is sharply upward sloping. The inflation risk premium explains 23% (42%) of the time variation in the five (ten)-year forward risk premium and it plays an important role in help explain deviations from the expectations hypothesis of interest rates.

Introduction

An enormous literature discusses the estimation and properties of dynamic models of the term structure of interest rates. A significant part of this literature focuses on reduced-form affine models.1 In this paper, first we study the link between these models and the real business cycle literature. We then quantify the properties of the inflation risk premium and study the ability of a general equilibrium model to explain deviations from the expectations hypothesis of interest rates.

The first generation of (completely) affine models makes three assumptions to derive implications about the nominal yield curve. First, the spot interest rate is an affine function of a set of mean-reverting state variables with constant or square-root local volatility. Second, the price of risk is a constant multiple of the local interest rate volatility. Third, inflation is neutral so that the Fisher relation between nominal and real interest rates holds.

Empirical studies of this class of models have exposed several limitations. With regards to the second assumption, Duffee (2002) shows that the restriction on the market price of risk implies bond returns and Sharpe ratios that are too high with respect to the empirical evidence. Dai and Singleton (2000) show that this same assumption makes affine models unable to explain the extent of the deviation from the expectations hypothesis of interest rates. They state that “a three factor CIR-style [Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross] model is wholly incapable of matching linear projection yield (LPY ) coefficients. We attribute this model failure to the constraint in CIR-style models that risk premiums are proportional to factor volatilities”. With regards to the third assumption, there is mounting evidence against the Fisher neutrality assumption. Benninga and Protopapadakis (1983), Fama (1990), and Boudoukh (1993) find that the inflation rate is negatively related to the real interest rate in terms of both realized changes and expected values. Moreover, real returns on nominal bonds decline when inflation increases (Fama, 1976b, Fama, 1990, Fama and Gibbons, 1982).2

Partially in response to these limitations, recent studies have explored more flexible models. Duffee (2002) and Dai and Singleton (2000) estimate reduced-form (essentially) affine models in which the price of risk is specified as a more general (ad hoc) function of the state variables. They identify and discuss the specific features that improve the empirical performance of this class of models.

In this paper, instead of assuming these features as exogenous, we develop and estimate a structural model in which some of these features arise in equilibrium. We explore a monetary version of a real business cycle production economy in which, in equilibrium, the term structure of interest rates has the following properties. First, although the state variables follow affine stochastic processes, the market price of risk is not a constant multiple of the local volatility of interest rates. Second, the inflation risk premium is positive and time varying, i.e., the Fisher hypothesis does not hold. Third, the previous two features make the term structure deviate from the expectations hypothesis of interest rates. Thus, the model can potentially match the empirical LPY coefficients.

The structural model allows us to identify the underlying nominal and real factors and to address a number of economic questions. However, this approach has its shortcomings. First, it shares the known limitations of real business cycle models (Cooley and Hansen, 1995). Second, while the market price of risk is state-dependent, it is not as flexible as the one advocated in the reduced-form approach by Duffee (2002). We study the extent to which the model can describe the dynamics of the term structure despite these limitations. Our structural model is classical in many respects: time-separable preferences, a representative agent, diffusive information, and a constant-returns-to-scale production function. Its main distinguishing features are as follows.

First, we assume a nominal fiscal system. This feature generates the departure from the Fisher hypothesis. In classical monetary real business cycle models, inflation and money are not neutral because if agents anticipate an increase in inflation, they substitute away from activities that use cash in favor of activities that do not. We explore a different and arguably more important channel of monetary nonneutrality. When the fiscal system is not indexed to the general price level, i.e., when taxes and fiscal incentives are calculated on nominal historical values, the inflation rate affects the after-tax real return on capital. This, in turn, affects ex ante decisions on the optimal allocation of (real) resources and therefore also affects both asset prices and risk premia (see Feldstein et al., 1978, Feldstein, 1980, Fisher and Modigliani, 1978). Examples of the nominal nature of the fiscal system include depreciation, capital gains, and interest payments on debt.3 When the fiscal system is based on nominal historical values, inflation is a risk factor with asset pricing implications. Given the dimension of the taxable base and tax rates, the fiscal system is of first-order importance.

Second, monetary policy is endogenous. Similar in spirit to a Taylor (1993) policy rule, the money supply consists of a constant long-term rate plus a term that depends on the gap between the current levels of inflation and output and their long-term targets. This feature allows us to distinguish between exogenous monetary shocks and monetary injections motivated by real shocks.

Third, the real marginal productivity of capital follows a square-root process with stochastic drift. The state variables affecting the drift follow square-root processes with correlated Brownian motions. This setup can capture differential effects of the state variables on the marginal productivity of capital. Under certain parameter configurations, the state variables can independently affect either the instantaneous return on capital or its local variance. This allows us to model separately the uncertainty (unexpected innovations) in the marginal productivity of capital and the volatility of expected innovations in the marginal productivity of capital. We show the importance of this feature to generating a state-dependent market price of risk.

We begin by fully characterizing the stochastic equilibrium of the model. We then estimate the structural parameters using U.S. Treasury bond data and study a number of economic implications. We address several questions. First, can a classical monetary business cycle model generate an affine term structure with a price of risk sufficiently flexible to address Duffee's critique? We show a model that generates an endogenous equilibrium market price of risk that is not a constant multiple of the interest rate volatility. The price of risk is state-dependent and can explain the conditional volatility of interest rates better than a traditional CIR model.

Second, what is the size of the U.S. inflation risk premium? We find that over the last 40 years, the average one-month inflation risk premium has been 15 basis points. However, the average ten-year inflation risk premium has been 70 basis points. The term structure of the inflation risk premium is sharply upward sloping, with the long-term inflation risk premium about four times larger than the short-term premium. The size of the long-term inflation risk premium is a large component of the yield spread between nominal and real bonds. Moreover, the inflation risk premium shows time variation over the business cycle, from 20 to 140 basis points.

Third, can a structural model explain the size of the deviation from the expectations hypothesis (EH) of interest rates? What structural reasons drive such deviations? Our monetary model generates a highly time-varying forward risk premium. The extent of time-variation is sufficient to reject the EH. We analytically solve for the model-implied Campbell-Shiller (1991) regression coefficients. We find that they are not statistically different from those obtained by Campbell and Shiller using empirical data. We then decompose the total risk premium into two components. The first is generated by monetary shocks and the second by real shocks. We find that the monetary factor accounts for 43% of the time variation of the risk premium.

This paper draws on contributions from several streams of literature. In addition to the reduced-form affine term structure literature, discussed earlier, our asset pricing model is closely related to monetary versions of real business cycle models.4 As such, our model inherits many of their advantages and disadvantages. For instance, in the absence of frictions, time-separable real business cycle models find it difficult to replicate output growth persistence (Cooley and Hansen, 1995) and the equity premium. For this reason, classical real business cycle models have been generalized to incorporate nominal rigidities, more realistic financial intermediation mechanisms, and nonseparable preferences. Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987) study a static economy with both wage and price stickiness. Chari et al. (1996) consider a more general real business cycle model with price stickiness. Erceg (1997), Erceg et al. (2000), and Huang and Liu (1999) analyze the effects of exogenous monetary policy shocks in a model with wage contracts à la Taylor. Christiano et al. (2001) consider a model with staggered wage contracts and variable capital utilization. They show that these nominal rigidities can account for observed inertia in inflation and persistence in output. Although they do not derive explicit implications for the inflation risk premium, it is reasonable to expect that these nominal rigidities would increase the inflation risk premium, implied by models with no frictions, by distorting the optimal allocation of capital and increasing the persistence of monetary and technological shocks.

Cooley and Nam, 1998, Dai and Singleton, 2000 study a different monetary channel. They incorporate a debt-contracting problem with costly verification into a standard real business cycle model with limited participation. Financial intermediaries are initially uninformed and must pay a price to obtain information. This feature affects loan intermediation and amplifies the response of capital to the money supply shock.5

Our work is also related to Bakshi and Chen (1996), who study a monetary economy in which positive monetary holdings are supported in equilibrium. They derive closed-form solutions for the nominal term structure of interest rates in a model that abstracts from tax distortions. The main differences in our model are: (a) the monetary policy is endogenous (the nominal money supply is allowed to change in response to deviations from monetary and real targets); (b) we introduce taxes in the model and allow for an imperfect indexation mechanism to nominal shocks; and (c) we let the investment opportunity set be affected by inflation innovations so that there exists a (time-varying) risk premium on the inflation rate. The equilibrium process of the general price level is affected by both supply and demand factors. Our results are also related to Evans (1998), who uses data on U.K. index-linked bonds to estimate the real term structure and the risk premium, and to Pennacchi (1991), who studies a generalized Vasiček economy with constant volatility in which the time series for the expected inflation is obtained from survey data as opposed to being estimated. An important advantage of our model is to allow the risk premia to be time varying.6 Other related papers include Longstaff and Schwartz (1992), Marshall, 1992, Masulis and DeAngelo, 1980, the two-factor Cox et al. (1985b) model, Constantinides (1992), and Duffie and Kan (1996). However, none of these papers explicitly account for the risk premium on the inflation rate.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets up the model and characterizes the equilibrium nominal and real term structures of interest rates. Section 3 describes empirical testable restrictions and the econometric method. Section 4 describes the dataset. Section 5 summarizes the results of estimating and testing the structural model. Section 6 illustrates the properties of the inflation risk premium. Section 7 explores the extent to which the model can explain deviations from the expectations hypothesis. Section 8 discusses the implications of the model in terms of conditional second moments. Section 9 studies the tradeoff between fitting asset prices and other macroeconomic variables. Section 10 concludes.

Section snippets

The structure of the economy

We consider an economy in which a single good is produced by a representative agent who can either consume or reinvest it in a constant-returns-to-scale production technology. Real monetary holdings are assumed to provide a transaction service because they reduce the total amount of resources needed to achieve a given level of net consumption. In this economy, money is held because of its positive marginal productivity in the “shopping technology”. Let the preferences U(t,Xt) of the

Econometric methods

In this section, we use the restrictions obtained in Propositions 1 and 2 to estimate and test the overidentified representation of the economy using panel data on nominal bond yields. We then study the properties of the term structure of the inflation risk premium. We estimate the model by quasi maximum likelihood (QML) as in Chen and Scott (1993), Fisher and Gilles (1996), and Duffee (2002). The procedure assumes that the covariance matrix of the measurement errors is not of full rank, so

The data

The empirical results are based on 492 monthly observations from January 1960 to December 2000. The dataset consists of three main components: interest rates, price levels, and money supply. Interest rate data from January 1960 to February 1991 are obtained from the McCulloch and Kwon dataset; see McCulloch (1990) and Kwon (1992). This database contains end-of-month zero-coupon yields and forward curves based on the McCulloch, 1975, McCulloch, 1990 methodology from one month to ten years. We

Empirical results

Litterman and Scheinkman (1991) find that three factors explain most of the Treasury yield curve movements. Their empirical evidence has prompted most of the term structure literature to focus on the estimation of three-factor models of the yield curve. In addition to convention, we find that the choice of three factors can be justified by running specification tests based on the approach by Andrews and Ploberger (1994) and Hansen (1996). These tests account for the parameters of the excluded

Cross-sectional properties

The average term structure of the inflation risk premium, calculated over the entire sample, is illustrated in Fig. 2, Panel D. The term structure is upward sloping. At a three-month horizon the inflation risk premium is 25 basis points, increasing to 70 basis points at a ten-year horizon.

The positive slope is due to two effects. First, it is usually more difficult to predict inflation at longer horizons. In the short term, the inflation rate behaves quite closely to a random walk. In the long

The expectations hypothesis

One of the most debated and studied financial relation is the expectations hypothesis, hereafter EH, of interest rates. If the EH were correct, at least in a statistical sense, one could use implied forward rates to obtain a good proxy for the expected future spot rate. Unfortunately, most of the empirical evidence rejects the EH hypothesis. Such empirical evidence is important since it suggests the existence of a time-varying risk premium and since the direction and magnitude of rejection can

The term structure of volatility

Completely affine models of the term structure impose severe restrictions on the structure of conditional second moments, as they are perfectly correlated with the price of risk. In our model, a component of monetary policy uncertainty, wt, affects the conditional mean of the stochastic discount factor (thus interest rates) but not its conditional volatility. This factor is not priced: it can affect the term structure of interest rate volatility without affecting expected excess returns. We

Real interest rates

Fig. 2, Panel A, illustrates the dynamics of the estimated short-term real interest rate. During the sample period 1960–2000, it ranges between -2% and 5%. The average short-term real rate is 2%, while the average long-term real rate is 2.5%. The correlation between short- and long-maturity real rates is small. The volatility of short-term real rates is substantially higher than the volatility of long-term real rates, which fluctuates around 2.5%. Table 3 shows the correlation matrix for the

Conclusions

In the theoretical part of the paper, we first show the link between a monetary version of a real business cycle model with taxes on nominal profits and the latest generation of (essentially) affine term structure models (i.e., Duffee, 2002, Dai and Singleton, 2000) in which the price of risk is not a constant multiple of interest rate volatility. Second, we characterize a structural model in which the inflation risk premium is positive and time varying. The source of this premium is the fiscal

References (79)

  • C.J. Erceg et al.

    Optimal monetary policy with staggered wage and price contracts

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2000)
  • J.P. Danthine et al.

    Superneutrality of money in a stochastic dynamic macroeconomic model

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (1987)
  • Q. Dai et al.

    Expectations puzzles, time-varying risk premium, and affine models of the term structure

    Journal of Financial Economics

    (2002)
  • J.C. Cox et al.

    The relation between forward prices and futures prices

    Journal of Financial Economics

    (1981)
  • G. Bekaert et al.

    On biases in tests of the expectation hypothesis of the term structure of interest rates

    Journal of Financial Economics

    (1997)
  • D.W.K. Andrews et al.

    Optimal tests when a nuisance parameter is present only under the alternative

    Econometrica

    (1994)
  • Ang, A., Bekaert, G., 2004. The term structure of real rates and expected inflation. Unpublished working paper,...
  • Backus, D., Telmer, C., Wu, L., 1999. Design and estimation of affine yield models. Unpublished working paper, Carnegie...
  • G.S. Bakshi et al.

    Inflation, asset prices, and the term structure of interest rates in monetary economies

    The Review of Financial Studies

    (1996)
  • R. Bansal et al.

    Term structure of interest rates with regime shifts

    Journal of Finance

    (2002)
  • J. Benhabib et al.

    Monetary policy and multiple equilibria

    American Economic Review

    (2001)
  • Benhabib, J., Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M., 1999. The perils of Taylor rules. CEPR Discussion Papers...
  • B. Bernanke et al.

    Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations

    American Economic Review

    (1989)
  • B. Bernanke et al.

    The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework

  • S. Benninga et al.

    Real and nominal interest rates under uncertaintythe Fisher theorem and the term structure

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1983)
  • O.J. Blanchard et al.

    Monopolistic competition and the effects of aggregate demand

    American Economic Review

    (1987)
  • J. Boudoukh

    An equilibrium model of nominal bond prices with inflation-output correlation and stochastic volatility

    Journal of Money, Credit and Banking

    (1993)
  • J.Y. Campbell et al.

    Yield spreads and interest rates movements, a bird's eye view

    The Review of Economic Studies

    (1991)
  • C.T. Carlstrom et al.

    Monetary shocks, agency costs, and the business cycles

    Economic Theory

    (1998)
  • K.C. Chan et al.

    An empirical comparison of alternative models of the short-term interest rates

    Journal of Finance

    (1992)
  • V.V. Chari et al.

    Sticky price models of the business cyclecan the contract multiplier solve the persistence problem?

    Econometrica

    (1996)
  • Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C., 2001. Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary...
  • Christiano, L.J., Rostagno, M., 2001. Money growth monitoring and the Taylor rule, NBER Working Paper...
  • R. Chen et al.

    Maximum likelihood estimation for a multifactor equilibrium model of the term structure of interest rates

    Journal of Fixed Income

    (1993)
  • Cochrane, J., Piazzesi, M., 2002. Bond Risk Premia, NBER Working Paper...
  • G.M. Constantinides

    A theory of the nominal term structure of interest rates

    Review of Financial Studies

    (1992)
  • J.C. Cox et al.

    An intertemporal general equilibrium model of asset prices

    Econometrica

    (1985)
  • J.C. Cox et al.

    A theory of the term structure of interest rates

    Econometrica

    (1985)
  • T.F. Cooley et al.

    Money and the business cycle

  • Cited by (104)

    • The term structure and inflation uncertainty

      2020, Journal of Financial Economics
    • Stock vs. Bond yields and demographic fluctuations

      2019, Journal of Banking and Finance
    • Endogenous asymmetric money illusion

      2019, Journal of Banking and Finance
      Citation Excerpt :

      Table 1 displays a sensible choice of parameter values used in this exercise. The numbers are in line with the values used in the studies by Buraschi and Jiltsov (2005), Basak and Yan (2010), and Leippold and Matthys (2015). Fig. 1 illustrates the effect of asymmetric money illusion on the price and premium of the risky asset.

    • Portfolio selection with inflation-linked bonds and indexation lags

      2019, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control
    View all citing articles on Scopus

    The authors want to thank Lars P. Hansen for several useful comments and suggestions on an earlier version of the paper, and Geert Bekaert, David Chapman, John Cochrane, George Constantinides, Ian Cooper, Silverio Foresi, Stefano Risa, Nizar Touzi, Raman Uppal, and seminar participants at Carnegie Mellon, The University of Chicago, Duke University, Insead, London Business School, University of Michigan, MIT Sloan School, Nortwestern University, UCLA, University of Rochester, Wharton, and the WFA Conference. Special thanks to the WFA Committee which awarded this paper the Best Paper Award in Investment.

    View full text