www.fgks.org   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Jump to content

Income elasticity of demand: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Vinophil (talk | contribs)
No edit summary
Revert. Non-neutral assertion, off-topic, inappropriate for lead.
Line 1: Line 1:
In economics, '''income [[Elasticity (economics)|elasticity]] of [[Supply and demand|demand]]''' measures the responsiveness of the demand for a good to a change in the income of the people demanding the good, [[ceteris paribus]]. It is calculated as the ratio of the percentage change in demand to the percentage change in income. For example, if, in response to a 10% increase in income, the demand for a good increased by 20%, the income elasticity of demand would be 20%/10% = 2. Many introductory textbooks employ terminology which can sometimes be confusing to students.<ref>http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1566272</ref>
In economics, '''income [[Elasticity (economics)|elasticity]] of [[Supply and demand|demand]]''' measures the responsiveness of the demand for a good to a change in the income of the people demanding the good, [[ceteris paribus]]. It is calculated as the ratio of the percentage change in demand to the percentage change in income. For example, if, in response to a 10% increase in income, the demand for a good increased by 20%, the income elasticity of demand would be 20%/10% = 2.


== Interpretation ==
== Interpretation ==

Revision as of 10:20, 3 October 2011

In economics, income elasticity of demand measures the responsiveness of the demand for a good to a change in the income of the people demanding the good, ceteris paribus. It is calculated as the ratio of the percentage change in demand to the percentage change in income. For example, if, in response to a 10% increase in income, the demand for a good increased by 20%, the income elasticity of demand would be 20%/10% = 2.

Interpretation

Inferior goods' demand falls as consumer income increases.
  • A negative income elasticity of demand is associated with inferior goods; an increase in income will lead to a fall in the demand and may lead to changes to more luxurious substitutes.
  • A positive income elasticity of demand is associated with normal goods; an increase in income will lead to a rise in demand. If income elasticity of demand of a commodity is less than 1, it is a necessity good. If the elasticity of demand is greater than 1, it is a luxury good or a superior good.
  • A zero income elasticity (or inelastic) demand occurs when an increase in income is not associated with a change in the demand of a good. These would be sticky goods.

Income elasticity of demand can be used as an indicator of industry health, future consumption patterns and as a guide to firms investment decisions. For example, the "selected income elasticities" below suggest that an increasing portion of consumer's budgets will be devoted to purchasing automobiles and restaurant meals and a smaller share to tobacco and margarine.[1]

Income elasticitites are closely related to the population income distribution and the fraction of a the product's sales attributable to buyers from different income brackets. Specifically when a buyer in a certain income bracket experiences an income increase, their purchase of a product changes to match that of individuals in their new income bracket. If the income share elasticity is defined as the negative percentage change in individuals given a percentage increase in income bracket, then the income-elasticity, after some computation, becomes the expected value of the income-share elasticity with respect to the income distribution of purchasers of the product. When the income distribution is described by a gamma distribution, the income elasticity is proportional to the percentage difference between the average income of the product's buyers and the average income of the population. (Bordley and McDonald, "Estimating Income Elasticitities from the Average Income of a Product's Buyers and the Population Income Distribution. " Journal of Business and Economic Statistics.

Mathematical definition

More formally, the income elasticity of demand, , for a given Marshallian demand function for a good is

or alternatively:

This can be rewritten in the form:

With income , and vector of prices . Many necessities have an income elasticity of demand between zero and one: expenditure on these goods may increase with income, but not as fast as income does, so the proportion of expenditure on these goods falls as income rises. This observation for food is known as Engel's law.

Selected income elasticities

  • Automobiles 2.46[2]
  • Books 1.44
  • Restaurant Meals 1.40
  • Tobacco 0.64
  • Margarine −0.20
  • Public Transportation −0.36[3]

Income elasticities are notably stable over time and across countries.[4]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Frank, Robert (2008).p. 125
  2. ^ Samuelson; Nordhaus (2001). p.94.
  3. ^ Frank (2008) 125.
  4. ^ Perloff, J. (2008). p.105.

References

  • Perloff, J. (2008). Microeconomics Theory & Applications with Calculus. Pearson. ISBN 9780321277947.
  • Samuelson; Nordhaus (2001). Microeconomics (17th ed.). McGraw-Hill.
  • Frank, Robert (2008). Microeconomics and Behavior (7th ed.). McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-007-126349-8.