www.fgks.org   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Jump to content

Diminishing returns: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Pfhenshaw (talk | contribs)
to mention the key issue up front, that the world plan is shift to growth without added physical activity
m Fixed typo.
 
(435 intermediate revisions by more than 100 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Economic theory}}
In [[economics]], '''diminishing returns''' (also called '''diminishing marginal returns''') refers to the natural limits for investing in physical economic activity. Some see those limits as being overcome by unlimited growth of immaterial wealth based only on information, making it theoretically possible to sustain limitless expansion of the economy as a whole.
{{More citations needed|date=August 2011}}


[[File:Diminishing Returns Graph.svg|thumb|upright=1.3|A curve of output against input. The areas of increasing, diminishing and negative returns are identified at points along the curve. There is also a point of maximum yield which is the point on the curve where producing another unit of output becomes inefficient and unproductive.]]
For physical economic activity it refers to how the [[Marginalism|marginal]] production of a [[Factors of production|factor of production]] starts to progressively decrease as the factor is increased, in contrast to the increase that would otherwise be normally expected. According to this relationship, in a production system with fixed and variable inputs (say factory size and [[Labour (economics)|labor]]), there will be a point beyond which each additional unit of the variable input (i.e., man-hours) yields smaller and smaller increases in outputs, also reducing each worker's mean productivity. Conversely, producing one more unit of output will cost increasingly more (owing to the major amount of variable inputs being used, to little effect).
{{Economics sidebar}}


In [[economics]], '''diminishing returns''' are the decrease in [[Marginalism|marginal]] (incremental) output of a [[production (economics)|production]] process as the amount of a single [[Factors of production|factor of production]] is incrementally increased, holding all other factors of production equal (''[[ceteris paribus]]'').<ref name=Britannica2017>{{cite web |url=https://www.britannica.com/topic/microeconomics |title=Diminishing Returns |author=<!--Not stated--> |date=2017-12-27 |website=Encyclopaedia Britannica |access-date=2021-04-22}}</ref> The law of diminishing returns (also known as the law of diminishing marginal productivity) states that in productive processes, increasing a factor of production by one unit, while holding all other production factors constant, will at some point return a lower unit of output per incremental unit of input.<ref name=Samuelson2001p110>{{cite book |first1=Paul A. |last1=Samuelson |author1-link=Paul Samuelson |first2=William D. |last2=Nordhaus |title=Microeconomics |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2001 |isbn=0071180664 |pages=110 |edition=17th}}</ref><ref name=Erickson2014p44>{{cite book |last=Erickson |first=K.H. |date=2014-09-06 |title=Economics: A Simple Introduction |location= |publisher=CreateSpace Independent Publishing Platform|page=44 |isbn=978-1501077173}}</ref> The law of diminishing returns does not cause a decrease in overall production capabilities, rather it defines a point on a production curve whereby producing an additional unit of output will result in a loss and is known as negative returns. Under diminishing returns, output remains positive, but [[productivity]] and [[efficiency]] decrease.
This concept is also known as the '''law of diminishing marginal returns''' or the '''law of increasing relative cost'''.


The modern understanding of the law adds the dimension of holding other outputs equal, since a given process is understood to be able to produce co-products.<ref name=":0" /> An example would be a factory increasing its saleable product, but also increasing its CO<sub>2</sub> production, for the same input increase.<ref name="Samuelson2001p110" /> The law of diminishing returns is a fundamental principle of both micro and macro economics and it plays a central role in [[production theory basics|production theory]].<ref>{{cite book|title=Encyclopædia Britannica|date=26 Jan 2013|publisher=Encyclopædia Britannica, Inc.|isbn=9781593392925|url=https://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/163723/diminishing-returns}}</ref>
==Statement of the law==


The concept of diminishing returns can be explained by considering other theories such as the concept of [[exponential growth]].<ref name="khanacademy.org">{{Cite web|title=Exponential growth & logistic growth (article)|url=https://www.khanacademy.org/science/ap-biology/ecology-ap/population-ecology-ap/a/exponential-logistic-growth|access-date=2021-04-19|website=Khan Academy|language=en}}</ref> It is commonly understood that growth will not continue to rise exponentially, rather it is subject to different forms of constraints such as limited availability of resources and capitalisation which can cause [[economic stagnation]].<ref>{{Cite web |title=What Is Stagflation, What Causes It, and Why Is It Bad? |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/s/stagflation.asp |access-date=2023-04-23 |website=Investopedia |language=en}}</ref> This example of production holds true to this common understanding as production is subject to the four [[factors of production]] which are land, labour, capital and enterprise.<ref>{{Cite web |title=What are the Factors of Production |url=https://www.stlouisfed.org/education/economic-lowdown-podcast-series/episode-2-factors-of-production |access-date=2023-04-23 |website=www.stlouisfed.org |language=en}}</ref> These factors have the ability to influence [[economic growth]] and can eventually limit or inhibit continuous exponential growth.<ref>{{Cite web|title=What is Production? {{!}} Microeconomics|url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/wmopen-microeconomics/chapter/what-is-production/|access-date=2021-04-19|website=courses.lumenlearning.com}}</ref> Therefore, as a result of these constraints the production process will eventually reach a point of maximum yield on the production curve and this is where marginal output will stagnate and move towards zero.<ref name=PichèreYEARp17>{{cite book |last=Pichère |first=Pierre |date=2015-09-02 |title=The Law of Diminishing Returns: Understand the fundamentals of economic productivity |location= |publisher=50Minutes.com |page=17 |isbn=978-2806270092}}</ref> Innovation in the form of technological advances or managerial progress can minimise or eliminate diminishing returns to restore productivity and efficiency and to generate profit.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Knowledge, Technology and Complexity in Economic Growth |url=https://rcc.harvard.edu/knowledge-technology-and-complexity-economic-growth |access-date=2023-04-23 |website=rcc.harvard.edu |language=en}}</ref>
The law of diminishing returns has been described as one of the most famous laws in all of economics.<ref>Samuelson & Nordhaus, Microeconomics, 17th ed. page 110. McGraw Hill 2001.</ref> In fact, the law is central to production theory, one of the two major divisions of neoclassical microeconomic theory. The law states "that we will get less and less extra output when we add additional doses of an input while holding other inputs fixed. In other words, the marginal product of each unit of input will decline as the amount of that input increases holding all other inputs constant."<ref>Samuelson & Nordhaus, Microeconomics, 17th ed. page 110. McGraw Hill 2001.</ref> Explaining exactly why this law holds true has sometimes proven problematic. Preeminent economists have attributed the diminution in output to the fact that there are "too many" workers who get in each other's way; rather thin reasoning for the foundational law of production theory.<ref>The triteness of this explanation is more apparent when one realizes that in neoclassical production theory practically all concepts are flows rather than stocks. there are not units of labor there are flows of labor. In fact there are no factories in the brick and mortar sense = merely a point of confluence of flows of capital and labor that are immediately transformed into a flow of good which are instantaneously consumed.</ref>


This idea can be understood outside of economics theory, for example, population. The population size on Earth is growing rapidly, but this will not continue forever (exponentially). Constraints such as resources will see the population growth stagnate at some point and begin to decline.<ref name="khanacademy.org"/> Similarly, it will begin to decline towards zero but not actually become a negative value, the same idea as in the diminishing rate of return inevitable to the production process.
Diminishing returns and diminishing marginal returns are not the same thing. Diminishing marginal returns means that the MP<sub>L</sub> curve is falling. The output may be either negative or positive. Diminishing returns means that the extra labor causes output to fall which means that the MP<sub>L</sub> is negative. In other words the change in output per unit increase in labor is negative and total output is falling.<ref>Perloff, Microeconomics, Theory and Applications with Calculus page 178. Pearson 2008.</ref>


[[File:Diminishing Returns Graphs.svg|thumb|Figure 2: Output vs. Input [top] & Output per unit Input vs. Input [bottom]
==History==


Seen in [top], the change in output by increasing input from L<sub>1</sub> to L<sub>2</sub> is equal to the change from L<sub>2</sub> to L<sub>3</sub>.

Seen in [bottom], until an input of L<sub>1</sub>, the output per unit is increasing. After L<sub>1</sub>, the output per unit decreases to zero at L<sub>3</sub>.

Together, these demonstrate diminishing returns from L<sub>1</sub>.

]]

==History==
{{Expand section|date=December 2009}}
{{Expand section|date=December 2009}}


The concept of diminishing returns can be traced back to the concerns of early economists such as [[Johann Heinrich von Thünen]], [[Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune|Jacques Turgot]], [[Adam Smith]],<ref>{{cite book|last=Smith|first=Adam|title=The wealth of nations|publisher=Thrifty books|isbn=9780786514854}}</ref> [[James Steuart (economist)|James Steuart]], [[Thomas Robert Malthus]], and <ref name=PichèreYEARp9>{{cite book |last=Pichère |first=Pierre |date=2015-09-02 |title=The Law of Diminishing Returns: Understand the fundamentals of economic productivity |location= |publisher=50Minutes.com |pages=9–12 |isbn=978-2806270092}}</ref> [[David Ricardo]]. The law of diminishing returns can be traced back to the 18th century, in the work of Jacques Turgot. He argued that "each increase [in an input] would be less and less productive."<ref>{{Citation |title=Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot (1727–1781) |url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Turgot.html |encyclopedia=[[The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics]] |edition=2nd |series=[[Library of Economics and Liberty]] |publisher=[[Liberty Fund]] |year=2008 |access-date=16 July 2013 |archive-date=2 December 2019 |archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20191202210659/https://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Turgot.html |url-status= live }}<!-- NOTE: This is an original article not available from any other source. --></ref> In 1815, David Ricardo, Thomas Malthus, [[Edward West]], and [[Robert Torrens (economist)|Robert Torrens]] applied the concept of diminishing returns to land rent. These works were relevant to the committees of Parliament in England, who were investigating why grain prices were so high, and how to reduce them. The four economists concluded that the prices of the products had risen due to the [[Napoleonic Wars]], which affected international trade and caused farmers to move to lands which were undeveloped and further away. In addition, at the end of the Napoleonic Wars, grain imports were restored which caused a decline in prices because the farmers needed to attract customers and sell their products faster.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Brue |first=Stanley L |date=1993-08-01 |title=Retrospectives: The Law of Diminishing Returns |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |language=en |volume=7 |issue=3 |pages=185–192 |doi=10.1257/jep.7.3.185 |issn=0895-3309|doi-access=free }}</ref>
The concept of diminishing returns can be traced back to the concerns of early economists such as [[Johann Heinrich von Thünen]], [[Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, Baron de Laune|Turgot]], [[Thomas Malthus]] and [[David Ricardo]]. However, classical economist such as Malthus and Ricardo attributed the successive diminishment of output to the decreasing quality of the inputs. Neoclassical economists assume that each "unit" of labor is identical = perfectly homogeneous. Diminishing returns are due to the disruption of the entire productive process as additional units of labor are added to a fixed amount of capital.


Classical economists such as Malthus and Ricardo attributed the successive diminishment of output to the decreasing quality of the inputs whereas [[Neoclassical economics|Neoclassical economists]] assume that each "unit" of labor is identical. Diminishing returns are due to the disruption of the entire production process as additional units of labor are added to a fixed amount of capital. The law of diminishing returns remains an important consideration in areas of production such as farming and agriculture.
==A simple example==
Suppose that one kilogram of seed applied to a plot of land of a fixed size produces one ton of crop. You might expect that an additional kilogram of seed would produce an additional ton of output. However, if there are diminishing marginal returns, that additional kilogram will produce less than one additional ton of crop ([[ceteris paribus]]). For example, the second kilogram of seed may only produce a half ton of extra output. Diminishing marginal returns also implies that a third kilogram of seed will produce an additional crop that is even less than a half ton of additional output, say, one quarter of a ton.


Proposed on the cusp of the [[Industrial Revolution|First Industrial Revolution]], it was motivated with single outputs in mind. In recent years, economists since the 1970s have sought to redefine the theory to make it more appropriate and relevant in modern economic societies.<ref name=":0" /> Specifically, it looks at what assumptions can be made regarding number of inputs, quality, substitution and complementary products, and output co-production, quantity and quality.
In economics, the term "[[Marginalism|marginal]]" is used to mean on the edge of productivity in a production system. The difference in the investment of seed in these three scenarios is one kilogram &mdash; "marginal investment in seed is one kilogram." And the difference in output, the crops, is one ton for the first kilogram of seeds, a half ton for the second kilogram, and one quarter of a ton for the third kilogram. Thus, the [[marginal product|marginal physical product]] (MPP) of the seed will fall as the total amount of seed planted rises. In this example, the marginal product (or return) equals the extra amount of crop produced divided by the extra amount of seeds planted.


The origin of the law of diminishing returns was developed primarily within the agricultural industry. In the early 19th century, David Ricardo as well as other English economists previously mentioned, adopted this law as the result of the lived experience in England after the war. It was developed by observing the relationship between prices of wheat and corn and the quality of the land which yielded the harvests.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Cannan|first=Edwin|date=March 1892|title=The Origin of the Law of Diminishing Returns, 1813-15|url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/2955940|journal=The Economic Journal|volume=2|issue=5|pages=53–69|doi=10.2307/2955940|jstor=2955940}}</ref> The observation was that at a certain point, that the quality of the land kept increasing, but so did the cost of produce etc. Therefore, each additional unit of labour on agricultural fields, actually provided a diminishing or marginally decreasing return.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns: Definition, Example, Use in Economics |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/l/lawofdiminishingmarginalreturn.asp |access-date=2023-04-23 |website=Investopedia |language=en}}</ref>
A consequence of diminishing marginal returns is that as total investment increases, the total return on investment as a proportion of the total investment (the average product or return) decreases. The return from investing the first kilogram is 1 t/kg. The total return when 2&nbsp;kg of seed are invested is 1.5/2 = 0.75 t/kg, while the total return when 3&nbsp;kg are invested is 1.75/3 = 0.58 t/kg.


==Example==
Another example is a factory that has a fixed stock of capital, or tools and machines, and a variable supply of labor. As the firm increases the number of workers, the total output of the firm grows but at an ever-decreasing rate. This is because after a certain point, the factory becomes overcrowded and workers begin to form lines to use the machines. The long-run solution to this problem is to increase the stock of capital, that is, to buy more machines and to build more factories.
[[File:Total, Average, and Marginal Product.svg|thumb|right|''Figure 2 [OLD]: Total Output vs. Total Input [top] & Output per unit Input vs. Total Input [bottom]''


Seen in TOP, the change in output by increasing output from L<sub>1</sub> to L<sub>2</sub> is equal to the change from L<sub>2</sub> to L<sub>3</sub>.
==Returns and costs==
There is an inverse relationship between returns of inputs and the cost of production. Suppose that a kilogram of seed costs one [[dollar]], and this price does not change; although there are other costs, assume they do not vary with the amount of output and are therefore [[fixed cost]]s. One kilogram of seeds yields one ton of crop, so the first ton of the crop costs one extra dollar to produce. That is, for the first ton of output, the [[marginal cost]] (MC) of the output is $1 per ton. If there are no other changes, then if the second kilogram of seeds applied to land produces only half the output of the first, the MC equals $1 per half ton of output, or $2 per ton. Similarly, if the third kilogram produces only ¼ ton, then the MC equals $1 per quarter ton, or $4 per ton. Thus, diminishing marginal returns imply increasing marginal costs. This also implies rising average costs. In this numerical example, average cost rises from $1 for 1 ton to $2 for 1.5 tons to $3 for 1.75 tons, or approximately from 1 to 1.3 to 1.7 dollars per ton.


Seen in BOTTOM, until an output of L<sub>1</sub>, the output per unit is increasing. After L<sub>1</sub>, the output per unit decreases to zero at L<sub>3</sub>.
In this example, the marginal cost equals the extra amount of money spent on seed divided by the extra amount of crop produced, while [[average cost]] is the total amount of money spent on seeds divided by the total amount of crop produced.


Together, these demonstrate diminishing returns from L<sub>1</sub>.]]
Cost can also be measured in terms of [[opportunity cost]]. In this case the law also applies to societies; the opportunity cost of producing a single unit of a good generally increases as a society attempts to produce more of that good. This explains the bowed-out shape of the [[production possibilities frontier]].


A common example of diminishing returns is choosing to hire more people on a factory floor to alter current manufacturing and production capabilities. Given that the capital on the floor (e.g. manufacturing machines, pre-existing technology, warehouses) is held constant, increasing from one employee to two employees is, theoretically, going to more than double production possibilities and this is called '''increasing returns.'''
==Returns to scale==


If 50 people are employed, at some point, increasing the number of employees by two percent (from 50 to 51 employees) would increase output by two percent and this is called '''constant returns.'''
The marginal returns discussed refer to cases when only ''one'' of many inputs is increased (for example, the quantity of seed increases, but the amount of land remains constant). If all inputs are increased in proportion, the result is generally constant or increased output.


Further along the production curve at, for example 100 employees, floor space is likely getting crowded, there are too many people operating the machines and in the building, and workers are getting in each other's way. Increasing the number of employees by two percent (from 100 to 102 employees) would increase output by less than two percent and this is called "diminishing returns."
As a firm in the long-run increases the quantities of all factors employed, all other things being equal, initially the rate of increase in output may be more rapid than the rate of increase in inputs, later output might increase in the same proportion as input, then ultimately, output will increase less proportionately than input.


After achieving the point of maximum output, employing additional workers, this will give '''negative returns.'''<ref>{{Cite web |date=2016-04-12 |title=The Law of Diminishing Returns - Personal Excellence |url=https://personalexcellence.co/blog/diminishing-returns/ |access-date=2022-04-29 |website=personalexcellence.co |language=en-US}}</ref>
{{See also|economies of scale}}

Through each of these examples, the floor space and capital of the factor remained constant, i.e., these inputs were held constant. By only increasing the number of people, eventually the productivity and efficiency of the process moved from increasing returns to diminishing returns.

To understand this concept thoroughly, acknowledge the importance of '''marginal output''' or [[marginal return]]s. Returns eventually diminish because economists measure productivity with regard to additional units (marginal). Additional inputs significantly impact efficiency or returns more in the initial stages.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Law of Diminishing Returns & Point of Diminishing Returns Definition|url=https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/knowledge/economics/point-of-diminishing-returns/|access-date=2021-04-26|website=Corporate Finance Institute|language=en-US}}</ref> The point in the process before returns begin to diminish is considered the optimal level. Being able to recognize this point is beneficial, as other variables in the production function can be altered rather than continually increasing labor.

Further, examine something such as the [[Human Development Index]], which would presumably continue to rise so long as '''GDP per capita''' (in Purchasing Power Parity terms) was increasing. This would be a rational assumption because GDP per capita is a function of HDI. Even GDP per capita will reach a point where it has a diminishing rate of return on HDI.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Cahill|first=Miles B.|date=October 2002|title=Diminishing returns to GDP and the Human Development Index|url=http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/13504850210158999|journal=Applied Economics Letters|language=en|volume=9|issue=13|pages=885–887|doi=10.1080/13504850210158999|s2cid=153444558|issn=1350-4851}}</ref> Just think, in a low income family, an average increase of income will likely make a huge impact on the wellbeing of the family. Parents could provide abundantly more food and healthcare essentials for their family. That is a significantly increasing rate of return. But, if you gave the same increase to a wealthy family, the impact it would have on their life would be minor. Therefore, the rate of return provided by that average increase in income is diminishing.

== Mathematics ==
Signify <math>Output = O \ ,\ Input = I \ ,\ O = f(I)</math>

Increasing Returns: <math>2\cdot f(I)<f(2\cdot I)</math>

Constant Returns: <math>2\cdot f(I)=f(2\cdot I)</math>

Diminishing Returns: <math>2\cdot f(I)>f(2\cdot I)</math>

=== Production function ===
There is a widely recognised production function in economics: ''Q= f(NR, L, K, t, E)'':

* The point of diminishing returns can be realised, by use of the second derivative in the above production function.
*Which can be simplified to: <big>''Q= f(L,K)''.</big>
* This signifies that output (Q) is dependent on a function of all variable (L) and fixed (K) inputs in the production process. This is the basis to understand. What is important to understand after this is the math behind '''Marginal Product.''' ''<big>MP= ΔTP/ ΔL.</big>'' <ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Carter|first1=H. O.|last2=Hartley|first2=H. O.|date=April 1958|title=A Variance Formula for Marginal Productivity Estimates using the Cobb-Douglas Function|url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1907592|journal=Econometrica|volume=26|issue=2|pages=306|doi=10.2307/1907592|jstor=1907592}}</ref>
* This formula is important to relate back to diminishing rates of return. It finds the change in total product divided by change in labour.
* The Marginal Product formula suggests that MP should increase in the short run with increased labour. In the long run, this increase in workers will either have no effect or a negative effect on the output. This is due to the effect of fixed costs as a function of output, in the long run.<ref>{{Cite web|title=The Production Function {{!}} Microeconomics|url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/wmopen-microeconomics/chapter/the-production-function/|access-date=2021-04-21|website=courses.lumenlearning.com}}</ref>

=== Link with Output Elasticity ===
Start from the equation for the Marginal Product: <math>{\Delta Out \over \Delta In_1}= {{f(In_2, In_1 +\Delta In_1)-f(In_1,In_2)} \over \Delta In_1}</math>

To demonstrate diminishing returns, two conditions are satisfied; marginal product is positive, and marginal product is decreasing.

[[Output elasticity|Elasticity]], a function of Input and Output, <math>\epsilon ={In\over Out}\cdot{\delta Out\over \delta In}</math>, can be taken for small input changes. If the above two conditions are satisfied, then <math>0<\epsilon <1</math>.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Robinson|first=R. Clark|date=July 2006|title=Math 285-2 - Handouts for Math 285-2 - Marginal Product of Labor and Capital|url=https://sites.math.northwestern.edu/~clark/285/2006-07/handouts/marginal.pdf|access-date=1 November 2020|website=Northwestern - Weinberg College of Arts & Sciences -Department of Mathematics}}</ref>

This works intuitively;

# If <math>{In\over Out}</math> is positive, since negative inputs and outputs are impossible,
# And <math>{\delta Out\over \delta In}</math> is positive, since a positive return for inputs is required for diminishing ''returns''

* Then <math>0<\epsilon</math>

# <math>{\delta Out \over Out}</math> is relative change in output, <math>{\delta In \over In}</math> is relative change in input
# The relative change in output is smaller than the relative change in input; ~input requires increasing effort to change output~

* Then <math>{\delta Out \over Out}/{\delta In \over In}={In\over Out}\cdot{\delta Out\over \delta In}=\epsilon < 1
</math>

==Returns and costs==
There is an inverse relationship between returns of inputs and the cost of production,<ref>{{Cite web|title=Why It Matters: Production and Costs {{!}} Microeconomics|url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/wmopen-microeconomics/chapter/why-it-matters-production/|access-date=2021-04-19|website=courses.lumenlearning.com}}</ref> although other features such as input market conditions can also affect production costs. Suppose that a kilogram of seed costs one [[dollar]], and this price does not change. Assume for simplicity that there are no [[fixed cost]]s. One kilogram of seeds yields one ton of crop, so the first ton of the crop costs one dollar to produce. That is, for the first ton of output, the [[marginal cost]] as well as the average cost of the output is per ton. If there are no other changes, then if the second kilogram of seeds applied to land produces only half the output of the first (showing diminishing returns), the marginal cost would equal per half ton of output, or per ton, and the average cost is per 3/2 tons of output, or /3 per ton of output. Similarly, if the third kilogram of seeds yields only a quarter ton, then the marginal cost equals per quarter ton or per ton, and the average cost is per 7/4 tons, or /7 per ton of output. Thus, diminishing marginal returns imply increasing marginal costs and increasing average costs.

Cost is measured in terms of [[opportunity cost]]. In this case the law also applies to societies – the opportunity cost of producing a single unit of a good generally increases as a society attempts to produce more of that good. This explains the bowed-out shape of the [[production possibilities frontier]].

== Justification ==

=== ''Ceteris paribus'' ===
Part of the reason one input is altered ''ceteris paribus'', is the idea of disposability of inputs.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Shephard|first=Ronald W.|date=1970-03-01|title=Proof of the law of diminishing returns|url=https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01289990|journal=Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie|language=en|volume=30|issue=1|pages=7–34|doi=10.1007/BF01289990|s2cid=154887748|issn=1617-7134}}</ref> With this assumption, essentially that some inputs are above the efficient level. Meaning, they can decrease without perceivable impact on output, after the manner of excessive fertiliser on a field.

If input disposability is assumed, then increasing the principal input, while decreasing those excess inputs, could result in the same "diminished return", as if the principal input was changed ''certeris paribus''. While considered "hard" inputs, like labour and assets, diminishing returns would hold true. In the modern accounting era where inputs can be traced back to movements of financial capital, the same case may reflect constant, or increasing returns.

It is necessary to be clear of the "fine structure"<ref name=":0">{{Cite journal|last1=Shephard|first1=Ronald W.|last2=Färe|first2=Rolf|date=1974-03-01|title=The law of diminishing returns|url=https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01289147|journal=Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie|language=en|volume=34|issue=1|pages=69–90|doi=10.1007/BF01289147|s2cid=154916612|issn=1617-7134}}</ref> of the inputs before proceeding. In this, ''ceteris paribus'' is disambiguating.


==See also==
==See also==
{{Portal|Economics}}
* [[Accelerating returns]]
{{cols|colwidth=21em}}
* [[Learning curve]] and [[Experience curve effects]]
* [[Diminishing marginal utility]]
* [[Diseconomies of scale]], does not assume fixed inputs, thus differing from 'diminishing returns'
* [[Diseconomies of scale]]
* [[Diminishing marginal utility#Marginal utility|Diminishing marginal utility]], also not to be mistaken for 'diminishing returns'
* [[Increasing returns]]
* [[Economies of scale]]
* [[Gold plating (project management)]]
* [[Learning curve]]
* [[Experience curve effects]]
* [[Liebig's Law of the minimum]]
* [[Marginal value theorem]]
* [[Marginal value theorem]]
* [[Moore's law]]
* [[Opportunity cost]]
* [[Opportunity cost]]
* [[Returns to scale]]
* [[Pareto efficiency]]
* [[Self-organized criticality]]
* [[Submodular set function]]
* [[Sunk-cost fallacy]]
* [[Tendency of the rate of profit to fall]]
* [[Tendency of the rate of profit to fall]]
* [[Analysis paralysis]]
* [[Teamwork]]
* [[Amdahl's law]]
{{colend}}


==References==
== References ==
=== Citations ===
{{reflist}}
{{Reflist}}


==Sources==
=== Sources ===
{{refbegin}}
* Case, Karl E. & Fair, Ray C. (1999). ''Principles of Economics'' (5th ed.). Prentice-Hall. ISBN 0-13-961905-4.
* {{cite book |last1=Case |first1=Karl E. |last2=Fair |first2=Ray C. |title = Principles of Economics |publisher=Prentice-Hall |year=1999 |isbn = 0-13-961905-4 |edition=5th }}
{{refend}}


{{Clear}}
[[Category:Economics laws]]
{{economics}}
[[Category:Production and organizations]]
{{Authority control}}
[[Category:Economics of production]]


[[Category:Economics laws]]
[[ar:قانون الإنتاجية المتناقصة]]
[[Category:Production economics]]
[[de:Ertragsgesetz]]
[[es:Ley de los rendimientos decrecientes]]
[[eu:Errendimendu beherakorren lege]]
[[fr:Loi des rendements décroissants]]
[[ko:수확 체감]]
[[it:Rendimenti marginali]]
[[he:תפוקה שולית פוחתת]]
[[ja:収穫逓減]]
[[pl:Prawo malejących przychodów]]
[[pt:Lei dos rendimentos decrescentes]]
[[ru:Закон убывающей доходности]]
[[sk:Zákon klesajúcich výnosov]]
[[sv:Avtagande avkastning]]
[[vi:Quy luật hiệu suất giảm dần]]
[[zh:邊際報酬遞減定律]]

Latest revision as of 07:17, 16 May 2024

A curve of output against input. The areas of increasing, diminishing and negative returns are identified at points along the curve. There is also a point of maximum yield which is the point on the curve where producing another unit of output becomes inefficient and unproductive.

In economics, diminishing returns are the decrease in marginal (incremental) output of a production process as the amount of a single factor of production is incrementally increased, holding all other factors of production equal (ceteris paribus).[1] The law of diminishing returns (also known as the law of diminishing marginal productivity) states that in productive processes, increasing a factor of production by one unit, while holding all other production factors constant, will at some point return a lower unit of output per incremental unit of input.[2][3] The law of diminishing returns does not cause a decrease in overall production capabilities, rather it defines a point on a production curve whereby producing an additional unit of output will result in a loss and is known as negative returns. Under diminishing returns, output remains positive, but productivity and efficiency decrease.

The modern understanding of the law adds the dimension of holding other outputs equal, since a given process is understood to be able to produce co-products.[4] An example would be a factory increasing its saleable product, but also increasing its CO2 production, for the same input increase.[2] The law of diminishing returns is a fundamental principle of both micro and macro economics and it plays a central role in production theory.[5]

The concept of diminishing returns can be explained by considering other theories such as the concept of exponential growth.[6] It is commonly understood that growth will not continue to rise exponentially, rather it is subject to different forms of constraints such as limited availability of resources and capitalisation which can cause economic stagnation.[7] This example of production holds true to this common understanding as production is subject to the four factors of production which are land, labour, capital and enterprise.[8] These factors have the ability to influence economic growth and can eventually limit or inhibit continuous exponential growth.[9] Therefore, as a result of these constraints the production process will eventually reach a point of maximum yield on the production curve and this is where marginal output will stagnate and move towards zero.[10] Innovation in the form of technological advances or managerial progress can minimise or eliminate diminishing returns to restore productivity and efficiency and to generate profit.[11]

This idea can be understood outside of economics theory, for example, population. The population size on Earth is growing rapidly, but this will not continue forever (exponentially). Constraints such as resources will see the population growth stagnate at some point and begin to decline.[6] Similarly, it will begin to decline towards zero but not actually become a negative value, the same idea as in the diminishing rate of return inevitable to the production process.

Figure 2: Output vs. Input [top] & Output per unit Input vs. Input [bottom] Seen in [top], the change in output by increasing input from L1 to L2 is equal to the change from L2 to L3. Seen in [bottom], until an input of L1, the output per unit is increasing. After L1, the output per unit decreases to zero at L3. Together, these demonstrate diminishing returns from L1.

History[edit]

The concept of diminishing returns can be traced back to the concerns of early economists such as Johann Heinrich von Thünen, Jacques Turgot, Adam Smith,[12] James Steuart, Thomas Robert Malthus, and [13] David Ricardo. The law of diminishing returns can be traced back to the 18th century, in the work of Jacques Turgot. He argued that "each increase [in an input] would be less and less productive."[14] In 1815, David Ricardo, Thomas Malthus, Edward West, and Robert Torrens applied the concept of diminishing returns to land rent. These works were relevant to the committees of Parliament in England, who were investigating why grain prices were so high, and how to reduce them. The four economists concluded that the prices of the products had risen due to the Napoleonic Wars, which affected international trade and caused farmers to move to lands which were undeveloped and further away. In addition, at the end of the Napoleonic Wars, grain imports were restored which caused a decline in prices because the farmers needed to attract customers and sell their products faster.[15]

Classical economists such as Malthus and Ricardo attributed the successive diminishment of output to the decreasing quality of the inputs whereas Neoclassical economists assume that each "unit" of labor is identical. Diminishing returns are due to the disruption of the entire production process as additional units of labor are added to a fixed amount of capital. The law of diminishing returns remains an important consideration in areas of production such as farming and agriculture.

Proposed on the cusp of the First Industrial Revolution, it was motivated with single outputs in mind. In recent years, economists since the 1970s have sought to redefine the theory to make it more appropriate and relevant in modern economic societies.[4] Specifically, it looks at what assumptions can be made regarding number of inputs, quality, substitution and complementary products, and output co-production, quantity and quality.

The origin of the law of diminishing returns was developed primarily within the agricultural industry. In the early 19th century, David Ricardo as well as other English economists previously mentioned, adopted this law as the result of the lived experience in England after the war. It was developed by observing the relationship between prices of wheat and corn and the quality of the land which yielded the harvests.[16] The observation was that at a certain point, that the quality of the land kept increasing, but so did the cost of produce etc. Therefore, each additional unit of labour on agricultural fields, actually provided a diminishing or marginally decreasing return.[17]

Example[edit]

Figure 2 [OLD]: Total Output vs. Total Input [top] & Output per unit Input vs. Total Input [bottom] Seen in TOP, the change in output by increasing output from L1 to L2 is equal to the change from L2 to L3. Seen in BOTTOM, until an output of L1, the output per unit is increasing. After L1, the output per unit decreases to zero at L3. Together, these demonstrate diminishing returns from L1.

A common example of diminishing returns is choosing to hire more people on a factory floor to alter current manufacturing and production capabilities. Given that the capital on the floor (e.g. manufacturing machines, pre-existing technology, warehouses) is held constant, increasing from one employee to two employees is, theoretically, going to more than double production possibilities and this is called increasing returns.

If 50 people are employed, at some point, increasing the number of employees by two percent (from 50 to 51 employees) would increase output by two percent and this is called constant returns.

Further along the production curve at, for example 100 employees, floor space is likely getting crowded, there are too many people operating the machines and in the building, and workers are getting in each other's way. Increasing the number of employees by two percent (from 100 to 102 employees) would increase output by less than two percent and this is called "diminishing returns."

After achieving the point of maximum output, employing additional workers, this will give negative returns.[18]

Through each of these examples, the floor space and capital of the factor remained constant, i.e., these inputs were held constant. By only increasing the number of people, eventually the productivity and efficiency of the process moved from increasing returns to diminishing returns.

To understand this concept thoroughly, acknowledge the importance of marginal output or marginal returns. Returns eventually diminish because economists measure productivity with regard to additional units (marginal). Additional inputs significantly impact efficiency or returns more in the initial stages.[19] The point in the process before returns begin to diminish is considered the optimal level. Being able to recognize this point is beneficial, as other variables in the production function can be altered rather than continually increasing labor.

Further, examine something such as the Human Development Index, which would presumably continue to rise so long as GDP per capita (in Purchasing Power Parity terms) was increasing. This would be a rational assumption because GDP per capita is a function of HDI. Even GDP per capita will reach a point where it has a diminishing rate of return on HDI.[20] Just think, in a low income family, an average increase of income will likely make a huge impact on the wellbeing of the family. Parents could provide abundantly more food and healthcare essentials for their family. That is a significantly increasing rate of return. But, if you gave the same increase to a wealthy family, the impact it would have on their life would be minor. Therefore, the rate of return provided by that average increase in income is diminishing.

Mathematics[edit]

Signify

Increasing Returns:

Constant Returns:

Diminishing Returns:

Production function[edit]

There is a widely recognised production function in economics: Q= f(NR, L, K, t, E):

  • The point of diminishing returns can be realised, by use of the second derivative in the above production function.
  • Which can be simplified to: Q= f(L,K).
  • This signifies that output (Q) is dependent on a function of all variable (L) and fixed (K) inputs in the production process. This is the basis to understand. What is important to understand after this is the math behind Marginal Product. MP= ΔTP/ ΔL. [21]
  • This formula is important to relate back to diminishing rates of return. It finds the change in total product divided by change in labour.
  • The Marginal Product formula suggests that MP should increase in the short run with increased labour. In the long run, this increase in workers will either have no effect or a negative effect on the output. This is due to the effect of fixed costs as a function of output, in the long run.[22]

Link with Output Elasticity[edit]

Start from the equation for the Marginal Product:

To demonstrate diminishing returns, two conditions are satisfied; marginal product is positive, and marginal product is decreasing.

Elasticity, a function of Input and Output, , can be taken for small input changes. If the above two conditions are satisfied, then .[23]

This works intuitively;

  1. If is positive, since negative inputs and outputs are impossible,
  2. And is positive, since a positive return for inputs is required for diminishing returns
  • Then
  1. is relative change in output, is relative change in input
  2. The relative change in output is smaller than the relative change in input; ~input requires increasing effort to change output~
  • Then

Returns and costs[edit]

There is an inverse relationship between returns of inputs and the cost of production,[24] although other features such as input market conditions can also affect production costs. Suppose that a kilogram of seed costs one dollar, and this price does not change. Assume for simplicity that there are no fixed costs. One kilogram of seeds yields one ton of crop, so the first ton of the crop costs one dollar to produce. That is, for the first ton of output, the marginal cost as well as the average cost of the output is per ton. If there are no other changes, then if the second kilogram of seeds applied to land produces only half the output of the first (showing diminishing returns), the marginal cost would equal per half ton of output, or per ton, and the average cost is per 3/2 tons of output, or /3 per ton of output. Similarly, if the third kilogram of seeds yields only a quarter ton, then the marginal cost equals per quarter ton or per ton, and the average cost is per 7/4 tons, or /7 per ton of output. Thus, diminishing marginal returns imply increasing marginal costs and increasing average costs.

Cost is measured in terms of opportunity cost. In this case the law also applies to societies – the opportunity cost of producing a single unit of a good generally increases as a society attempts to produce more of that good. This explains the bowed-out shape of the production possibilities frontier.

Justification[edit]

Ceteris paribus[edit]

Part of the reason one input is altered ceteris paribus, is the idea of disposability of inputs.[25] With this assumption, essentially that some inputs are above the efficient level. Meaning, they can decrease without perceivable impact on output, after the manner of excessive fertiliser on a field.

If input disposability is assumed, then increasing the principal input, while decreasing those excess inputs, could result in the same "diminished return", as if the principal input was changed certeris paribus. While considered "hard" inputs, like labour and assets, diminishing returns would hold true. In the modern accounting era where inputs can be traced back to movements of financial capital, the same case may reflect constant, or increasing returns.

It is necessary to be clear of the "fine structure"[4] of the inputs before proceeding. In this, ceteris paribus is disambiguating.

See also[edit]

References[edit]

Citations[edit]

  1. ^ "Diminishing Returns". Encyclopaedia Britannica. 2017-12-27. Retrieved 2021-04-22.
  2. ^ a b Samuelson, Paul A.; Nordhaus, William D. (2001). Microeconomics (17th ed.). McGraw-Hill. p. 110. ISBN 0071180664.
  3. ^ Erickson, K.H. (2014-09-06). Economics: A Simple Introduction. CreateSpace Independent Publishing Platform. p. 44. ISBN 978-1501077173.
  4. ^ a b c Shephard, Ronald W.; Färe, Rolf (1974-03-01). "The law of diminishing returns". Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie. 34 (1): 69–90. doi:10.1007/BF01289147. ISSN 1617-7134. S2CID 154916612.
  5. ^ Encyclopædia Britannica. Encyclopædia Britannica, Inc. 26 Jan 2013. ISBN 9781593392925.
  6. ^ a b "Exponential growth & logistic growth (article)". Khan Academy. Retrieved 2021-04-19.
  7. ^ "What Is Stagflation, What Causes It, and Why Is It Bad?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-23.
  8. ^ "What are the Factors of Production". www.stlouisfed.org. Retrieved 2023-04-23.
  9. ^ "What is Production? | Microeconomics". courses.lumenlearning.com. Retrieved 2021-04-19.
  10. ^ Pichère, Pierre (2015-09-02). The Law of Diminishing Returns: Understand the fundamentals of economic productivity. 50Minutes.com. p. 17. ISBN 978-2806270092.
  11. ^ "Knowledge, Technology and Complexity in Economic Growth". rcc.harvard.edu. Retrieved 2023-04-23.
  12. ^ Smith, Adam. The wealth of nations. Thrifty books. ISBN 9780786514854.
  13. ^ Pichère, Pierre (2015-09-02). The Law of Diminishing Returns: Understand the fundamentals of economic productivity. 50Minutes.com. pp. 9–12. ISBN 978-2806270092.
  14. ^ "Anne-Robert-Jacques Turgot (1727–1781)", The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics, Library of Economics and Liberty (2nd ed.), Liberty Fund, 2008, archived from the original on 2 December 2019, retrieved 16 July 2013
  15. ^ Brue, Stanley L (1993-08-01). "Retrospectives: The Law of Diminishing Returns". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 7 (3): 185–192. doi:10.1257/jep.7.3.185. ISSN 0895-3309.
  16. ^ Cannan, Edwin (March 1892). "The Origin of the Law of Diminishing Returns, 1813-15". The Economic Journal. 2 (5): 53–69. doi:10.2307/2955940. JSTOR 2955940.
  17. ^ "Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns: Definition, Example, Use in Economics". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-23.
  18. ^ "The Law of Diminishing Returns - Personal Excellence". personalexcellence.co. 2016-04-12. Retrieved 2022-04-29.
  19. ^ "Law of Diminishing Returns & Point of Diminishing Returns Definition". Corporate Finance Institute. Retrieved 2021-04-26.
  20. ^ Cahill, Miles B. (October 2002). "Diminishing returns to GDP and the Human Development Index". Applied Economics Letters. 9 (13): 885–887. doi:10.1080/13504850210158999. ISSN 1350-4851. S2CID 153444558.
  21. ^ Carter, H. O.; Hartley, H. O. (April 1958). "A Variance Formula for Marginal Productivity Estimates using the Cobb-Douglas Function". Econometrica. 26 (2): 306. doi:10.2307/1907592. JSTOR 1907592.
  22. ^ "The Production Function | Microeconomics". courses.lumenlearning.com. Retrieved 2021-04-21.
  23. ^ Robinson, R. Clark (July 2006). "Math 285-2 - Handouts for Math 285-2 - Marginal Product of Labor and Capital" (PDF). Northwestern - Weinberg College of Arts & Sciences -Department of Mathematics. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  24. ^ "Why It Matters: Production and Costs | Microeconomics". courses.lumenlearning.com. Retrieved 2021-04-19.
  25. ^ Shephard, Ronald W. (1970-03-01). "Proof of the law of diminishing returns". Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie. 30 (1): 7–34. doi:10.1007/BF01289990. ISSN 1617-7134. S2CID 154887748.

Sources[edit]

  • Case, Karl E.; Fair, Ray C. (1999). Principles of Economics (5th ed.). Prentice-Hall. ISBN 0-13-961905-4.