www.fgks.org   »   [go: up one dir, main page]

Academia.eduAcademia.edu
THE FRAMING OF CLIMATE CHANGE AND DEVELOPMENT: A Comparative Analysis of the Human Development Report 2007/8 and the World Development Report 2010 Des Gasper, Ana Victoria Portocarrero, Asuncion Lera St.Clair Pre-publication version of a paper in Global Environmental Change, 23(2013), pp. 28-39. 1. Introduction The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) fourth Assessment report has shown how the relations between development pathways and climate change vulnerability, adaptation and impacts present fundamental challenges for our generation and those that will follow (IPCC 2007). Multilateral organizations working on development issues and poverty reduction have started to assess the implications of climate change for their work. The impacts of climate change will in general affect more strongly the low-latitude developing countries and poor people and communities across the planet. The IPCC Special Report on extreme weather events, for example, shows how socio-economic conditions substantially determine the extent of a disaster (IPCC 2012). Communities with little social power are, similarly, more likely to be negatively affected by policy responses to climate change such as forest protection and agro-fuels cultivation (Barnett and O’Neill 2010; Marino and Ribot 2012). The connections between climate change and development are, however, deeply contentious, partly because of the inverse relation between vulnerability to climate change and responsibility for the change. There are disagreements too over whether market-based growth can and should be the leading tool to address both poverty and climate change. Diverse perspectives and narratives have emerged. This paper analyses and compares the major statements on climate change and development of probably the two most prominent international development policy agencies: the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) and the World Bank, whose perspectives often cascade to other agencies and governments around the world (UNIHP, Stone 2012). In late 2007 UNDP published its Human Development Report 2007/8 on the connections between climate change and development, the HDR 2007/8. The World Bank followed with the World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change, WDR 2010, published in 2009 on the eve of the Copenhagen conference. These two reports are particularly influential amidst the increasing policy-oriented literature on the tensions and relations 1 between climate change and development. Ideas in these reports become legitimized as expert knowledge and communicated to a large variety of users (McNeill and St. Clair 2009; Mosse 2011; Stone 2012). We compare the Overviews of the two reports, using a frame- and content- analysis methodology. We focus on their key terms and ideas, framing choices, similarities and differences. We contextualize this analysis by reference to studies of how the institutions work and of past experiences in the processes of knowledge production leading to their Reports. While giving some attention to the Reports as a whole, which are of book-length, we concentrate on the very substantial Overviews. The Overviews are by far the most read and most influential sections, and are the most carefully prepared, reflecting an interplay between knowledge and politics that is typical for intergovernmental organizations (Broad 2007, Mosse 2011; St. Clair 2006a). Close reading and content analysis of the Overviews will provide insights into different worldviews that are prominent in the climate and development debate. In the next section we present the organisational and intellectual contexts of the reports and for understanding their influence. Section 3 summarizes the methodology of frame- and content- analysis. Section 4 compares the problem diagnoses in the two Overviews; how they frame the challenge of climate change. Section 5 then compares how they frame the approach to policy in response to that problem. Section 6 sums up our key findings, and notes areas for further work. 2. The nature and influence of the Human and World Development Reports: organizational, intellectual and situational contexts Global development organizations attempt to be agenda-setters, normsetters, and knowledge-brokers. They operate in a global arena of multiple actors who try to exert influence through use of discursive as well as material power. Documents such as the annual global Development Reports form key channels for this and compete for legitimacy and attention from the academic and policy communities. They aim to offer policy guidance but also, and as a prerequisite, to demonstrate expertise. A large body of research has analysed these processes of knowledge production in global multilateral institutions showing how it is a complex co-production involving in-house experts, consultants, and policy makers framing, reframing and editing. The products are ‘travelling rationalities’ (Craig and Porter 2006), standardized packages of knowledge framing and solutions framing, that reach out to national governments, practitioners and other knowledge networks and frame issues in particular ways (see e.g.; McNeill and St.Clair 2009; Mosse 2011; Stone and Wright 2006; Stone 2012). But unlike a knowledge organization like for example the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), which does not conduct research but rather assesses in a comprehensive manner existing 2 published academic papers, most UN specialized agencies and especially the World Bank produce their own knowledge often based on their own existing ideas and publications (Mosse 2011; St.Clair 2006a, 2006b). The World Bank is known amongst global development researchers and practitioners as ‘the Bank’. It is the largest source of knowledge for development worldwide, given an enormous research budget and capacity to access financing for events, gathering and distributing data, and promoting and disseminating its ideas through diverse mechanisms. Furthermore, the intellectual production of the Bank acquires special weight given the lending role the Bank plays, both directly and in coordinating consortia, and the support it draws from countries such as the United States and other global financial actors. The ideas presented in WDRs thus have direct and major influence on policy-making in client countries’ governments and on bilateral donor countries. Much work on the Bank has revealed the roles of politics and power in its processes of knowledge production and the frequent scientific and policy disagreements, especially in preparation of the Bank’s flagship report, the World Development Reports (Broad 2007, Goldman 2005, Lawson 2009, Mawdsley and Riggs 2003, McNeill and St.Clair 2011; Stone and Wright 2006; Stone 2012; Wade 2001). The World Development Reports are produced by the World Bank’s research and data arm, the Development Economics Vice-Presidency, and are supervised by the Chief Economist. World Development Reports position the Bank as an expert in global debates about development and poverty reduction, and have major impact. For example, the World Development Report 2000/01 has framed the subsequent approaches to poverty by many donor countries and governments in developing countries, despite the publicized disagreements on its policy recommendations and scientific basis which had led to the resignation of the lead editor (Kanbur 2001, Wade 2001). The World Development Report 2008 on agriculture came down in favour of market-led industrial agribusiness above small-scale agriculture and local food sovereignty, rejecting views in the intergovernmental assessment of agricultural knowledge, science and technology (IAAST) of which the Bank itself was a participant (Feldman and Biggs 2011). The Bank’s conclusions displaced in many policy circles serious attention to agricultural models that were considered more sustainable and equitable by the IAAST. The Bank returns to ideas that small– scale agriculture is inefficient and that local knowledge and local agricultural practices must give way to market forces (McMichael 2009). This sort of framing and policy power, as well as the repeated use of political power in the research process, has been analysed in regards also to the WDRs’ framing of equity and development and to the attempted subsumption of a whole discipline, geography, to economic analysis (Lawson 2009; McNeill and St.Clair 2011; Rigg et al 2009). Many scholars who have explored the Bank’s knowledge 3 production processes describe them as self-referential and dominated by reductionist economic thinking. (Besides references above, see Wade 2002.) Draft WDRs are scrutinized by country representatives in the Bank’s Board of Governors and must be approved by the Executive Board of Directors. They tend to become statements of the ‘institutional message’. Because of the need to maintain a sense of coherence in an organization that is highly heterogeneous and complex, new ideas and themes tend to be built upon older and well established Bank ideas; critical views are excluded, in what Wade (1996) and Broad (2006) call ‘the art of paradigm maintenance’. Disagreements are resolved in closed-door interactions. Ideas that are not suited to the tools of analysis and instruments of policy of the Bank (for example, the role of human rights in bringing about fair development processes) tend to be excluded (McNeill & St.Clair 2011). Unusually, the 2010 WDR was co-directed by an outsider, Rosina Bierbaum, Dean of Environment at the University of Michigan, working with Bank economist Marianne Fay. The Bank also has sections that promote more socially aware perspectives. For example, the former head of the social development department, Steen Jorgensen, co-authored a paper that argues for a ‘no regrets’ approach to climate change and an important role for social protection mechanisms (Heltberg, Siegel, and Jorgensen, 2009). But the WDR 2010 matches instead the Strategic Framework for the World Bank Group (WBG), which represents the formal institutional position of the Bank. This states that the Bank can no longer avoid addressing climate change as part of its ongoing work on poverty reduction and development, but that its mandate is to focus on building growth and reducing poverty (St.Clair 2010). The document emphasises expanding business opportunities in relation to energy efficiency, and stresses that ‘resources will not be diverted from financing core development needs’ (World Bank 2008: 5). The core business of the Bank— promoting and funding huge investments, often in fossil-fuel based sectors, as in the recent $3 billion loan for the coal-fired Medupi power plant in South Africa—tends to overshadow its intellectual engagement in issues of climate change (Storm, 2011). In contrast, the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP)’s historical and intellectual evolution has had a more open character, even if, like any knowledge organization, it has its own investments in particular ideas and theoretical perspectives (McNeill and St.Clair 2009; Murphy 2006). UNDP has evolved from an agency created to coordinate UN technical and scientific assistance to less developed countries (LDCs) on a project basis, to become a policy agency that provides advice, advocacy and resources. It has achieved an intellectual leadership role particularly since the creation of the Human Development Report Office (HDRO), which has published the annual global Human Development Report from 1990 onwards. This Report’s ‘human 4 development paradigm’ was the result of a partnership between especially the late Mahbub ul Haq, as the first HDRO Director, and the economist Amartya Sen. ‘Human development’ has become a morally grounded conception of development, supported by Sen’s capability approach that conceptualises development as extension of the range of attainable ‘doings and beings’ that people have reason to value. An orientation also to human rights grew under later HDRO directors, including from 2004 to 2008 Kevin Watkins, former research director of Oxfam. Watkins was lead author for the HDR 2007/8. The HDRs’ ability to articulate this alternative perspective relies on the independent position of the HDRO vis a vis the governments in the board of UNDP. The HDRO is located officially outside UNDP. This gives it more freedom to criticise the status quo, though it can later limit the ‘clout’ that its ideas have at country level (McNeill and St.Clair 2009). The human development paradigm has helped to revive UNDP as a leading multilateral (Murphy 2006) despite its tiny funding compared to the World Bank, but this does not mean it automatically achieves policy influence. Since the 1990s, the gap in ideas between these two multilateral organizations has reduced, as the Bank has increasingly opened up to acknowledging the complexity of development processes and the multidimensionality of poverty. However, although both organizations endorse the target of reducing emissions so that warming does not exceed a 2 degrees average, the two differ significantly in how they frame the challenge of climate change in relation to development, as we will see. 3. Methodology: frame- and content-analysis We undertake a frame-analysis of the two Overviews, supported and disciplined by content-analysis. Sections 4 and 5 will present a systematic comparison of the Overviews’ ideas, inclusions and exclusions. This is grounded in, first, attention to the Reports’ socio-political context and the organisations and units responsible, as sketched already in section 2; and, second, in content-analysis, with special attention to lexical choice since a vocabulary conveys a world-view, a pattern of attention and perception. The present section explains the methodology. Frames are ‘underlying structures of belief, perception and appreciation’ (Schön & Rein 1994: 23). De Boer et al. give a similar definition: ‘[the set of] organizing principles that enable a particular interpretation of a phenomenon’ (2010: 502). People see and think in terms of systems of meanings, but much of the patterning of language-use is unconscious; language users inherit and absorb standardised ‘packages’ of norms, conventions and usages, that operate beneath the level of full conscious control. Frame theory, of various types, looks at this patterning (e.g., Benford and Snow, 2000; Goffman, 1974; Kahneman and Tversky, 1984; Lakoff 2001). A mental frame directs and 5 organises attention: it includes or highlights some things, occludes or omits others, and links the included features together in a sense-making pattern that suggests relationships and gives order to complexity. In policy discussions a policy-frame adds an orientation towards action. Schön and Rein (1994)’s form of policy-frame analysis gives special attention to the choices of metaphor and of value-stance which guide and sustain this orientation process. Frame analysis can be essayed too casually. Sometimes one does better to use the verb, framing, rather than the noun, frame, if the latter leads one to underestimate the range of patterns that people employ and combine. Presumptions about the presence of standard versions of already-known frames (‘neo-liberal’/ ‘Marxist’/…) in the work of others vitiate much casual discourse analysis. A leading critical discourse theorist opens a recent textbook with this warning: “Usually in the social sciences, text sequences are used as illustrations, sentences are taken out of context, and specific text sequences are used to validate or reject claims without relating them to the entire textual material and without providing any explicit justification or external evidence for their selection” (Wodak, 2008:1). Correspondingly, serious ‘Discourse Analysis Means Doing Analysis’—methods-based analysis across all of a text— in the words of Antaki et al. (2003). They warn against reliance on assertions of the presence in a text of mega-discourses (‘neo-liberal’/…) on the basis of a few supportive quotations, and against overgeneralization beyond the analysed texts. Genuine discourse analysis combines close contextual analysis with systematic attention to both the micro- and macro-structures of texts (van Dijk 2009; Wodak 2008). We respond to this challenge by essaying a detailed contextual, structural, and micro-textual analysis of the whole of the centrepiece of each of our two Reports: the self-contained Overview section. We include word-frequency comparisons for the whole of the Overviews. Simple frequency counts that show very large differences will help to indicate different world-views, since the two Overviews have almost exactly the same length: 11,000 words, excluding notes, references, and supplementary boxes. (See also Fløttum and Dahl 2012.) The HDR Overview is available in two versions: as part of the full report (pp.1-18), and as a longer self-standing document on the HDR website (http://hdr.undp.org/en/media/HDR_20072008_Summary_English.pdf, pp.7-30 of a 31 page ‘Summary’ file that also contains tables, diagrams, the frontmatter, Foreword, contents list, etc.). Page references and wordcounts that we give in this paper are to the self-standing version (), since that is more comparable to the WDR Overview, which also contains tables and diagrams; we add page references to the full report version in square brackets. Wordcounts for the WDR Overview (pp.1-29) will exclude its References section since the HDR Overview has no such section.Word counts were done via Adobe Acrobat 7.0. 6 Besides formal content analysis, using word counts across a whole text, we use several of the methods for systematic micro-analysis that Alexander (2009) presents and illustrates in his investigation of discourses on environment. He advises careful attention to the following: 1. Terms of praise (‘purr terms’), terms of belittling and ridicule, and euphemisms, for each of these give hints regarding implied conclusions; 2. The usages of ‘we’ and ‘our’, for they imply a choice of viewpoint and loyalties; 3. Choices of metaphors, for these embody and convey a perspective more powerfully than does abstracted language; 4. Definitions (including through searching for uses of ‘as’, ‘define’, etc.); 5. ‘Naturalizing’, whereby some things are declared or assumed to be natural, normal, inevitable or the like; 6. ‘Nominalization’, the replacement of processverbs by nouns, which similarly exaggerates the fixity or inevitability of present arrangements and removes attention from their possible reform; 7. The concealment of agency by use of passive verbs, which again serves to naturalize and divert attention from responsibility and changeability; 8. Recurrent vocabulary; and 9. What the recurrent and key terms (like ‘we’) are paired with, the immediately adjacent words. We pay special attention to aspects 1-5 and 8. Yanow (2000) brings together many such methods in an integrated approach to interpretive policy analysis. Schmidt (2006) does the same in his similar adaptation of Rein’s ‘value-critical policy analysis’, which gives special attention to the value choices that guide the selections and combinations made in framing. Table 1 below summarizes these approaches and lists some of the methods relevant in each stage. Stages 1, 2, and 3 must often be done iteratively, but in our case the interpretive communities and artefacts are relatively clearcut. We look at the World Bank’s development economics research wing, at the Human Development Report Office in UNDP, and at the main publication by each on climate change and development. The chosen Reports are exactly comparable, and each was launched shortly before a UNFCCC Conference of the Parties annual meeting (those of 2007 and 2009) and sought to structure the thinking of parties involved in that process. We focus on their Overviews, since these are large-scale, widely distributed statements that represent the most publicly visible and intensively accessed statements on climate change by the two most prominent international development organizations, the World Bank and UNDP. Further, they are self-contained analyses that hardly even cross-refer to other chapters in the Reports. 7 Table 1: Stages in interpretive policy analysis YANOW (2000): ACTIVITIES/STAGES IN INTERPRETIVE POLICY ANALYSIS SOME RELEVANT METHODS 1. Identify interpretive communities 2. Identify key meaningladen artefacts, symbols (language, objects, and/or acts) 3. Identify the embodied systems of meanings Stakeholder analysis 4. Compare the systems used by different communities 5. Clarify sources of disagreements Compare systems in terms of components, scope, consistency etc. 6. Reflect, assess, perhaps synthesise Use of sector expertise and judgement Frame analysis, content analysis, category analysis, metaphor analysis, argument analysis Ditto All of the above SCHMIDT (2006): STAGES IN VALUECRITICAL ANALYSIS OF A POLICY DEBATE 1. Identifying the issue and the protagonists 2. Describing the context and the protagonists’ policy proposals 3. Describing the arguments and the core values, aspect by aspect, using sector-specific knowledge 4. Value-critical analysis of the core arguments and choices 5. Drawing conclusions; making recommendations The selection of aspects for description and comparison depends partly on general discourse analysis theory—for example Alexander’s checklist includes much of importance—but also on knowledge in the substantive area concerned and on detailed detective work within the texts under examination. Thus, in Section 4, for comparing how the two reports frame the problem of climate change in relation to development we look at the following: 1. The importance given to climate change; and for whom and for what it is considered a problem – for economic growth, for poor people, for future generations? 2. The grouping of countries, with reference to vulnerabilities and responsibilities. 3. The links seen between climate and development, with attention to meanings attached to ‘development’. 4. The specification of causal linkages and structural rigidities. 5. Usage of the term ‘efficiency’, including whether it is used to direct policy attention to activities in poor rather than rich countries. 6. How far the reports consider the field in terms of human rights. Some of these questions arise out of awareness of ongoing debates around climate change and development; some, including items 4 and 5, emerged from exploration of these specific texts; and in the case of item 6, a standard item 8 for comparison—degree of attention to human rights—grew in importance as a result of such exploration, as we will now illustrate. The HDR uses the same title for its Report and its Overview: Fighting Climate Change – Human solidarity in a divided world. The title provides an ethical and political message about struggle, division, and overcoming that division in order to face a shared crisis. It appeals to ideals of bravery, solidarity and human community. The Overview maintains this style. It opens with a quotation from Martin Luther King Jr., which urges people to confront ‘the fierce urgency of now’ and to take action, for ‘Over the bleached bones and jumbled residues of numerous civilizations are written the pathetic words: Too late.’ (p.7). The Report cites Gandhi and Chico Mendes in similar ways. Its call for solidarity is illustrated by its frequent use of the word ‘we’, which appears vastly more often in its Overview than in the closely similar length WDR Overview (56 usages versus 11). In contrast, the WDR 2010 adopts a bland Report title: Development and Climate Change. It sees a ‘challenge’ not a ‘fight’ (p.18). Its Overview has a separate title, Changing the Climate for Development. ‘Climate’ here refers not only to meteorological features but to conditions that influence development such as institutions, markets and political stability. The title conveys that the Report will describe how to manage this climate in order to achieve or enhance development. The message is not a political and ethical statement asserting a We, but a managerialist ‘Can-Do’ that reflects a framing of climate change as a challenge that can be tamed with sufficient funds and technology and matches the Bank’s predominant technocratic-bureaucratic style (McNeill and St. Clair 2009). The word ‘can’ appears more than twice as often in the WDR Overview than in the HDR one (77 uses versus 32). The WDR in effect takes as its motto ‘a climate-smart world is within reach’ (a section title on p.10). Although the Overview in the HDR does not use the term ‘ethical’ or ‘ethics’, ‘moral’ appears three times, ‘justice’ seven times (usually as ‘social justice’) and ‘human rights’ eleven times. It includes strong and repeated messages on ‘social justice and respect of human rights’ (p.13 [6]), and speaks of an impending ‘moral failure on a scale unparalleled in history’ (p.8 [2]) if we fail to prevent runaway climate change. The WDR Overview makes no use of the terms ‘ethical’, ‘moral’, ‘justice’, ‘human development’, ‘human security’ or even ‘human rights’. ‘Climate-smart’, a term that conveys technocratic orientation and can-do ability, appears nine times, versus not at all in the HDR Overview. ‘Equity’ and ‘equitable’ are the WDR’s vaguer preferred normative terms, appearing 15 times, versus twice in the HDR Overview. The WDR Overview uses even the terms ‘political’ and ‘politically’ just six times (compared to 23 times in the HDR Overview) and focuses instead on economic growth and on ‘efficiency’ or ‘efficient’ (48 uses, compared to 21). Unlike in the HDR, ´growth´ in the WDR Overview almost invariably means 9 economic growth. It asserts from the outset that: ‘Critical to the progress [in reducing poverty, lengthening lives and improving nutrition is]: rapid economic growth’ (p.1), and repeats this often. It conceals issues by referring to ‘growth and poverty alleviation’ as an indissoluble package, which it treats as a singular noun not a plural (p.1). The WDR Overview also gives much emphasis to economic calculations of efficiency and returns. It cites ‘a global average GDP loss of about 1 percent’ from climate change (p.5); and gives only one sentence at the end of a paragraph to the expected deaths from business-as-usual economic expansion: ‘And over 3 million additional people could die from malnutrition each year.’ (p.5). In contrast, the HDR focuses on human impacts more than on GDP. The first page of its Foreword says: ‘In terms of aggregate world GDP, these short term effects may not be large. But for some of the world’s poorest people, the consequences could be apocalyptic.’ (p.3 [v]). We will probe these radical differences in style and declared priorities, and then ask how far the two Reports differ in reality as policy frameworks. 4. Framing the problem In exploring how climate change is framed in each report, we look at the six themes identified in the previous section: 1. the importance given to climate change, and for whom and for what it is considered a problem; 2. the grouping of countries and attribution of responsibilities; 3. the links seen between climate and development, and the meaning given to ‘development’; 4. the specification of structural rigidities and their implications; 5. understandings and usage of the term ‘efficiency’; 6. how far is the field considered in human rights terms. 4.1. Importance and urgency of climate change – and for whom? The HDR presents climate change as the most urgent and grave problem of our times and as an ‘outrage to the conscience of mankind’ (p.10 [4]). The ‘battle’ against it ‘is part of the fight for humanity’ (p.13 [6]). (The HDR Overview uses ‘fight’ or ‘fighting’ nine times, apart from in its title, and ‘battle’ six times. The WDR Overview never uses either term. ) The Foreword of the HDR makes a call to ‘act now’ (p.3 [v]), while the opening page of the Overview states (in 2007) that ‘The world has less than a decade to change course’ (p.7 [1]); its conclusion section portrays climate change as perhaps ‘the gravest threat ever to have faced humanity’ (HDR p.27 [15]). The Overview uses the term ‘danger’ or ‘dangerous’ in combination with ‘climate change’ 27 times compared to only three times (plus twice in its Notes) in the WDR Overview. 10 Specifically, the HDR highlights climate change as an inter-generational issue, for ‘our generation is running up an unsustainable ecological debt’ (p.9 [3]); as a human rights issue, for to allow runaway climate change ‘would represent a systematic violation of the human rights of the world’s poor and future generations’ (p.10 [4]); and as a human development issue, for ‘doing nothing offers a guaranteed route to […] mutually assured destruction of human development potential’ (p.12 [5]). It repeatedly uses ‘blunt’ language, including condemning the ‘complacency and prevarication that continues to characterize international negotiations on climate change’ (p.13 [6]). Underpinning this impatience is a notion of threshold: a danger point beyond which damage greatly accelerates. ‘Threshold(s)’ appears seven times in the HDR Overview, versus only once in the WDR Overview. The HDR notes (e.g., in Ch.1) that the idea has its own dangers. First, it sometimes elides the issue of ‘dangerous for whom?’ A stage of climate change that is not immediately dangerous for most of the affluent is already past the danger point for millions of poor people: ‘262 million people were affected by climate disasters annually from 2000 to 2004, over 98 percent of them in the developing world’ (p.16 [8]); and ‘The 1 billion people currently living in urban slums on fragile hillsides or flood prone river banks face acute vulnerabilities’ (p.18 [9]). Much of the human development damage is irreversible (p.19 [10]); being born in a drought year in a poor country, for example, markedly increases one’s likelihood to be malnourished years later (p.16 [9]). Second, the notion that we are not yet at the dangerous level, but are approaching it, is meant to generate a sense of urgency but it can operate in the reverse way, like the idea that there is a safe range for smoking. By giving the feeling that we have a safe space, it can induce inertia followed by the wistful hope that the real threshold is a bit further away than we were previously told. For example, the level of 450 ppm CO2-equivalent for greenhouse gases (GHGs) has widely become seen as a safe level, when it implies in fact a 50% chance of breaching the 2 degrees warming threshold. The HDR rightly points out that 450 ppm is not safe (p.14 [7]). But the unsafe supposedly safe level, or even higher levels, are widely converted into targets calling for cuts of ‘at least X’ which become diluted in political practice to mean ‘at most X’. In the WDR the 2 degrees ceiling itself quickly gets downplayed: ‘From the perspective of development, warming much above 2°C is simply unacceptable’ (p.3; emphasis added) – but warming a bit above 2 degrees is left implicitly as tolerable, certainly from other perspectives than ‘development’ (meaning there a concern for low-income nations and low-income people). For the WDR the target instead becomes ‘staying close to a 2°C warming’ (p.196). In comparison then to the WDR 2010 and some other prominent work, the HDR reads as bold and ethical, including in declaring already in 2007 450 ppm as the GHGs target (p.29 [17]) when the Stern Review for the UK 11 Government, led by the Bank’s former Chief Economist, had just adopted a target of 550 ppm as politically palatable, even though it had acknowledged elsewhere that ‘550 pm CO2-e would be a dangerous place to be’ (Stern 2007: 329). In face of the accumulating evidence of faster deterioration and greater risks, Stern (2010) later adjusted his target, though only to 500 ppm. The WDR portrayed climate change as an urgent issue, but considerably less urgent than in the HDR. The HDR Overview uses four times the idea of ‘window of opportunity’, a chance that must be taken within a fixed period or will be lost; the WDR Overview uses it not at all. Instead it presents figures of modest potential GDP losses: ‘a global average GDP loss of about 1 percent’ (p.5) and not more than a year’s foregone growth even in low-income countries. The figures are based on the relatively conservative 2007 IPCC climate projections and estimate the possible direct monetary costs of damage to agriculture, to coastal areas and so on; they ignore other human costs and the indirect impacts of social and political unrest, conflict and migration, such as presaged in the Darfur crisis. The WDR Overview gives considerable space instead to discussions by economists about balancing the estimated monetary values of direct costs of climate change against costs of mitigation: ‘In the major models, the benefits of stabilization exceed the costs at 2.5°C warming (though not necessarily at 2°C)’ (p.8), or even only perhaps at ‘well above 3°C’ (p.8). These ‘major models’ are by neoclassical economists who value effects according to market prices: ‘The optimal target is defined as the concentration that would result in the lowest reduction in the present value of global consumption’ (p.8); and they rely on in some cases obsolete estimates of the (in)sensitivity of various linkages. Such models do not impress many climate scientists (see e.g. The Independent, 2009). 4.2. Grouping of countries: responsibility versus vulnerability Climate change is a global problem because emissions in one location affect other locations. The reports agree that this justifies a response that includes all countries and that high-income countries ‘cannot continue to fill up an unfair and unsustainable share of the atmospheric commons’ (WDR p.1). Considering also countries’ different levels of development, both reports stress that countries should respond differently to the problem. Both reports, especially the WDR, proceed largely in terms of countries as the units of analysis, and divide them into two main groups. Both reports, especially the WDR, focus more on the victim, the developing countries. The picture of high-income economies is vaguer. We know from the Reports that they are substantially responsible for what is happening and will happen, but we do not learn much about how, nor about how the problems of power in high-income economies (HIEs) could be addressed. Additionally, the image of victim can deny LDCs their own voice 12 and capacity of action. The ‘responsible’-‘vulnerable’ divide, while valid, can be used to reinforce a system of international relations in which HIEs exert control over LDCs on the grounds that it is their responsibility (now using the word in a second sense) to be in charge. The HDR emphasises more strongly that while LDCs have contributed to climate change much less, they are more vulnerable to its impacts (e.g., p.9 [3]), but it retains the dualism just described. The inequalities in terms of causal responsibility and of vulnerability, as well as the special needs of more vulnerable groups, are held to justify financial transfers from high-income countries to LDCs. 4.3. The climate-development link and the meaning of development Both reports then emphasize that climate change is an obstacle for development, the advance of low-income countries; that ‘High levels of poverty and low levels of human development limit the capacities of poor households to manage climate risks’ (HDR p.16 [8]); that climate change is ‘drawing resources away from development’ (WDR p.1); and that high-income countries must reduce their emissions, but that developing countries still need ‘massive expansions’ (WDR p.1). They differ, however, on what trade-offs they see and indeed in how they interpret ‘development’. Climate change is placed by the WDR, from the outset, in a subordinate relation to ‘development’. It largely uses the concepts of development and (economic) growth interchangeably. For example, mitigation can be ‘without sacrificing growth’ (p.1), and, a few sentences later, is ‘compatible with furthering development’ (p.2). The same equivalence is found in successive sentences in the middle of the next column on p.2 and in many other places. The only difference in the WDR’s usage of the two terms appears to be that ‘development’ is reserved for low-income countries. Damage is discussed largely in terms of GDP. The conception of development in the HDR is ‘human development’, ‘human well-being and prosperity’ (p.3 [v]). It discusses damage in terms of people's quality of life and questions the dominant paradigm that equates development to unending economic growth. There could be no clearer demonstration than climate that economic wealth creation is not the same thing as human progress. Under the current energy policies, rising economic prosperity will go hand-in-hand with mounting threats to human development today and the well-being of future generations. But carbon-intensive growth is symptomatic of a deeper problem. One of the hardest lessons taught by climate change is that the economic model which drives growth, and the profligate consumption in rich nations that goes with it, is ecologically unsustainable. (UNDP, 2007: 15). 13 While the WDR Overview says virtually nothing on such issues for rich countries, the HDR Overview reiterates the message in its Conclusion: ‘economic wealth creation is not the same thing as human progress’ (p.27 [15]); and even if it were: ‘the profligate consumption in rich nations […] is ecologically unsustainable’ (p.27 [15]). But the HDR seems internally divided: the next paragraph in the Conclusion says ‘with the right reforms, it is not too late to cut greenhouse gas emissions to sustainable levels without sacrificing economic growth: […] rising prosperity and climate security are not conflicting objectives’ (p.27 [15]). To restrict this judgment to only low-income countries appears to have been too politically sensitive for a Conclusion section, even in the HDR. The WDR argues that some climate change policies have co-benefits in terms of growth and that climate change policy is not a choice between growth and the environment. The two goals can be combined, though particular patterns of consumption and production are dangerous. Development remains treated as economic growth, but new ways of growing have to be devised. The WDR goes further: ‘there is no reason to think that a low-carbon path must necessarily slow economic growth’ (p.7): no reason, even though climateproofing redirects resources and even though reorientation takes time. The arguments given are economic not ecological and consist of analogies with past environmental regulations. Here is a second fundamental premise in the WDR (the first being that economic growth is required to remove poverty): economic growth does not need to be slowed in order to avoid dangerous climate change. This certainty is not shaken by evidence elsewhere in the WDR, such as that: ‘the coal-fired power plants proposed around the world over the next 25 years are so numerous that their lifetime CO2 emissions would equal those of all coal-burning activities since the beginning of the industrial era. Only those facilities located close enough to the storage sites could be retrofitted for carbon capture and storage (if and when that technology becomes commercially available)’ (p.11). Investments already envisaged for the next couple of decades may lock the world into a high-emissions pattern. 4.4. System inertia -- hence a policy focus on LDCs ? Both the HDR and the WDR address ‘inertia’ in the processes around climate change, using also other metaphors. The WDR applies the theme to more issues and declares ‘Inertia is the defining characteristic of the climate challenge’ (WDR: p.3). The first type of inertia, which both reports address, concerns the nature of climate change: the emissions of today affect GHG concentrations, temperatures and sea levels for hundreds or even thousands of years. So a delay in mitigation now makes it almost impossible to avoid crossing the threshold of 2ºC warming that both reports warn against. 14 Both reports also consider inertia in economies. If changes are not made today in LDCs’ investment patterns, their economies will become ‘locked’— like those of rich countries, it is argued—in patterns of production that will be very difficult and costly to change in the future. If already developed economies are seen as ‘locked’ in a specific model of production and consumption that is hyper-expensive to ‘unlock’, then it is efficient to invest to avoid this model being adopted by LDCs. That the HDR Overview uses the structuralist language of ‘lock’ (seven uses, versus the WDR Overview’s five) and ‘trap’ (five uses) is not surprising. But the WDR employs also the language of ‘inertia’ in development processes, which leads in the same direction, and it highlights two further types of inertia that reduce speed of response. The next type affects research and development. According to the WDR, the time required for innovation and development of new technologies and energy sources is nearly always long. So, one must invest now in order to have the required technology and systems when they will be needed. The final type of inertia is related to the ‘ingrained’ behavior of individuals and organizations, which is difficult to change (p.20). The WDR mentions high risk-aversion, social norms that rigidify patterns of consumption and production, and the ways in which political leaders and managers make decisions. This last type of inertia, added to the previous ones including especially the rigidity of economies, implies the need to re-direct people's behaviour at many levels, especially in the presently ‘un-locked’ LDCs (see e.g. pp.17-18). Overall, the physical metaphors of locking and inertia give a picture, especially in the WDR, of high-income economies as fixed in their models of production and consumption. So the policy focus should be on economies that are not yet fixed, those of the LDCs. The framing of the problem leads to the framing of the solution. In the WDR the focus on LDCs is furthered also by the interpretation given to ‘efficiency’. 4.5 The ‘efficiency’ shift of attention regarding reduction of emissions, from HIEs to LDCs Unlike the WDR, the HDR refers to power when analyzing the causes of the lack of emission reductions in HIEs. It points out that power imbalances between countries, and between different groups within the same country (let alone between the living and the unborn), have determined the negotiations agendas and their unsatisfactory results. Lobbying by powerful business groups is one reason why ‘caps on emissions have been set far too high’ in the European Union’s Trading System (HDR p.20 [11]). In contrast, in the entire WDR, a huge report, of the over 200 usages of ‘power’ and ‘powerful’, none relate to power imbalances or powerful groups. A key concept in both reports, but especially the WDR, through which attention is shifted to reduction of emissions in LDCs, is ‘efficiency’. 15 According to the HDR ‘[l]ow levels of energy efficiency in developing countries are currently a threat to climate change mitigation efforts’ (HDR p.22 [12]). The WDR advocates cuts in subsidies and increases in taxes for energy in LDCs, to give incentives for more efficient use. It argues that the changes required in agricultural practices and in use of land and water are in LDCs, ‘because agriculture in high-income countries is already close to maximum feasible yields’ (p.17). LDC agriculture must become more productive without increasing environmental damage; it must become more efficient like that in HIEs. The WDR does not explain in terms of what values it considers agricultural practices efficient. Elements such as nutrition habits, cultural needs and ecological footprint, among others, are not considered in its assessments of what is ‘efficient’. Rural communities are assumed to be in need of modernization and technification, as it discusses in detail in its chapter 3. ‘Efficiency’ refers to the rate at which benefits are produced per quantum of resources invested; ‘efficient’ means attaining the maximum attainable net benefits. The relevant benefits and costs can be interpreted in narrower technical or financial/economic or broad social terms. If the required output is a certain reduction in emissions compared to what they would otherwise have been, it is efficient to invest in LDCs, the WDR states, because less resources are required to achieve the output. However, if the efficiency that concerns us is in terms of human development per unit of emissions, then, due to the enormous needs in the LDCs, might it be more efficient to cut emissions in HIEs and redistribute emission quotas to LDCs? Framing the problem in terms of ‘inertia’ and ‘efficiency’, as in the WDR, leads to putting the spotlight for policy action upon developing rather than rich countries. A focus on efficiency in energy use, as conventionally conceived, may shift attention from total emissions, for which HIEs are much more responsible, to inefficient usage, where LDCs are deemed worse. 4.6 A Human Rights issue? According to the HDR, climate change ‘raises profoundly important questions about social justice, equity and human rights across countries and generations’ (HDR p.8 [2]). The Report equates non-action in relation to climate change with a violation of human rights. It cites and endorses strong formulations such as ‘adaptation apartheid’ (pp.24 [13], 26 [18]) to describe a situation in which countries with more resources will be able to invest in adaptation, while countries with less income will not be prepared for the worst consequences of climate change. Hence the HDR calls for ‘stronger international commitment on adaptation’ (HDR p.13 [6]), in the name of human rights. In contrast, the WDR Overview makes no mention of human rights or ‘social justice’ . Later, a text-box on ‘Ethics and climate change’ in Chapter 1 touches on human rights (and has the Report’s one reference to ‘justice’; p.53). 16 It considers the possible use of human rights as a criterion to evaluate impacts of climate change, but focuses on use of formal legal channels within which responsibility and harm must be decisively proven, and so lists problems for taking human rights impact as a criterion in evaluation of climate change. Similar narrowly legal understanding is evident in the 2006 WDR on equity and development and in internal Bank debates about the role of rights (McNeill and St. Clair, 2011). However, law is not the only relevant channel for applying human rights concerns. Thus the HDR, in contrast, takes human rights as priority criteria that should influence policy-level design. In sum, the HDR frames the problem partly in terms of human rights and human development, with much emphasis on duties of rich countries. The WDR frames the problem more as one of inertia and inefficiency, with emphasis on adjustments in poor countries. In the next section we consider to what extent the differences in the problem-framings give rise to different proposed solutions. 5 Framing the solutions After the significantly different problem-framings, the solution-framings in the two Reports are considerably closer. Both present a model that includes these features: (1) Developing countries need more development. (2) High Income Economies should adopt carbon-pricing: either a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade system. (3) These mechanisms will generate funds that should be administered by a multilateral mechanism for transfer of finance and technology to LDCs for both mitigation and adaptation. (4) The transfers will be programme-based and conditional on LDC commitments to quantitative goals and policy changes in terms of mitigation, adaptation and management of resources such as water, land, and energy. (5) More reliance on competitive markets. Less on the surface, while recognising that major emissions cuts must happen in high-income economies if the 2ºC ceiling is to be respected the reports accept that in a world of nation-states the rich nation-states are not forced to make commitments. No global enforcement mechanisms are proposed, nor any mechanism that would make financial commitments automatic and obligatory. Even the HDR does not draw many institutional implications from its arguments about human rights and who bears responsibility for past damage. It does recommend ‘a national carbon budget in all developed countries with targets for reducing overall emissions from a 1990 reference year incorporated into national legislation’ (p.29). But it fails to clarify the principles of responsibility that are to guide action – which mixture of the principles of causal responsibility (‘polluter pays’) and response-ability (‘ability to pay’) does it advocate, asks Opschoor (2008: 1199). The WDR stays with 17 the vague term ‘equity’, and remains ‘singularly unclear about the principle of equity which should underlie [its proposed] global deal’ (Storm, 2011: 402). The reports implicitly appeal to the following: in the HDR, feelings of sympathy; in both reports, an enlightened self-interest that is able to look beyond today and tomorrow to the longer-term; and, perhaps combining the two (Opschoor, 2008), identification of win-win options. Enlightened selfinterest is often advocated, especially in the WDR, in the unthreatening language of ‘insurance’; unthreatening because it does not highlight the implied appeal to show concern also for future generations. At some points the WDR comes close to calling on rich countries to extend their calculations in terms of ‘self’ to their children and children’s children: ‘the losses implied by delays are so large that there are clear economic benefits for high-income countries committed to limiting dangerous climate change to finance early action in developing countries’ (WDR, p.12). The WDR makes no claim on the basis of broader sympathy and solidarity with poor countries. We look first at the nature of the Reports’ commitment to more growth; second at the ideas about insurance; and then at some of the detailed individual proposals. 5.1. The intermediary means: more growth Both reports see fighting climate change and fighting poverty as interrelated. According to the WDR, economic growth enhances the resilience of countries that are vulnerable to climate change. However, the Report also states that growth is not sufficient because it is not fast enough, can increase vulnerability to climate hazards, and is not equitable enough to assure that the poorest people will be protected (WDR p.7). Hence the Report advocates growth along a low-carbon path, with adaptation measures to take care of the more vulnerable. This is for low-income countries. We saw that for rich countries the HDR sometimes rejects an unending growth-strategy but sometimes hesitates. The WDR’s location in a development bank controlled by representatives of finance ministries in the US, Europe and Japan guarantees its silence on foregoing growth in rich countries. Instead it asserts that growth provides the resources to make all necessary transitions. ‘WDR 2010’s almost exclusive focus on “win-win” techno-fixes suggests, without solid grounds, that the structural shift to a low carbon path can all be painless—without sacrificing growth and development’ (Storm, 2011: 400). Storm explores the full Report and suggests the flimsy basis of many components and the incoherence of the overall structure: ‘…serious climate stabilization is not consistent with strong global income growth …. However much WDR 2010 wants us to believe it’ (p.415). 18 5.2. Insurance and the underlying ethics ‘Efficiency’ is a language of maximizing aggregate net benefits, whereas ‘insurance’ is about covering against possibilities which are known to exist at aggregate level but whose disaggregated occurrence at some lower level cannot be predicted reliably. The Reports, especially the WDR, employ both languages. They portray climate-change related investment as an insurance to avoid the worst consequences of climate change: a familiar reassuring framing. The HDR stresses that we have sufficient certainty about climate change – the evidence is ‘overwhelming’ (p.12 [5], 14 [7]), ‘the debate is over and climate scepticism is an increasingly fringe activity’ (12 [5]). US $1 of pre-disaster prevention and preparation ‘can prevent losses of US $7’ (p.24 [14]). However there is uncertainty about effects in detail and their distribution, so that an insurance rationale is relevant; ‘if we value the well-being of our children and grandchildren, even small risks of catastrophic events merit an insurance-based precautionary approach’ (p.8 [2]). Located next door to the US Congress and the fossil-fuel lobby, the World Bank is more cautious, but shares these conclusions. The WDR explains that given the difficulties of doing a simple cost-benefit analysis of climate change, plus the uncertainties about the potential ‘catastrophic risks’ of the phenomenon, it is justifiable to undertake ‘earlier and more aggressive action’, which can be seen as ‘climate insurance’ (WDR p.9). ‘Spending less than half a per cent of GDP [net] as “climate insurance” could well be a socially acceptable proposition’ (p.9). The WDR puts forward the argument for climate policy as insurance rather tentatively. It employs more hedging than normal, reflecting the implicit move beyond its usual aggregating economic cost-benefit calculations. The short paragraph about climate insurance on page 9 contains ‘may well’, ‘could be thought of’, and ‘could well be’. In contrast, hedging is absent when the Report later sums up its policy diagnosis, much of which is far more contentious: ‘The previous pages describe the many steps needed to manage the climate change challenge.’ (p.18). Why such hedging about insurance? An insurance argument in this context introduces an assumption of moral community, at some level or levels: across generations, within nations, between nations. Often the risks fall largely on the poor and the premiums on the rich. Climate change insurance is largely for the benefit of future generations, mostly abroad. Even if the argument is that HIEs should invest now in the efforts of developing countries in adaptation and mitigation, because this investment prevents future ‘catastrophic risks’ for all (p.9) – for example from an increase of migration flows from South to North due to climate change – there is a presumption of solidarity of the present day rich North with at least the future generations in the North. In other words the WDR discussion relies on moral premises that, unlike the HDR, it is not bold enough to recognize or discuss. 19 5.3 Proposals for mitigation and adaptation The WDR remains vague about emissions ceilings for rich countries, let alone for poor countries. Instead it uses a language of ‘acting together’ (pp. 3-4, 1011), in order to engage developing countries in the effort for mitigation and to involve HIEs in the effort for financing. Acting together diminishes mitigation costs for everyone; and postponing mitigation in developing countries because of lack of finances would greatly increase the cost of preventing more than a 2ºC temperature rise. In that sense, investing in mitigation in developing countries brings economic benefits not only for developing countries but for high-income countries as well. The HDR is again bolder. Its main mitigation strategy is for new emission limits for the post-2012 Kyoto Protocol period that must be consistent with the ‘global carbon budget’ (HDR p.19). That budget must be translated into ‘practical national strategies–and national carbon budgets’ (p.20 [10]). Reaching these emissions targets will be supported by grants and loans from a Climate Change Mitigation Facility (p.23 [12]). The HDR adds that ‘any multilateral agreement without quantitative commitments from developing countries will lack credibility in terms of climate change mitigation’ (HDR p.28 [16]). The target of avoiding more than 2ºC warming requires further that by 2050 rich nations reduce their emissions by at least 80 percent relative to levels of 1990, notes the HDR (p.15 [7]). While drawing on the same calculations from UNFCCC, IPCC and others, the WDR mentions the figure only in the fourth chapter of the whole Report, in a small text-box at the bottom of page 189, not in the Overview. The initial pages of the WDR address the importance of reducing emissions drastically, but the Overview does not state the percentage reductions required of HIEs. The WDR’s techno-optimism, married to a faith in the magic of markets, plus firm tutelage from HIE government representatives to the Bank, seem to result in leaving the details hazy. While the Bank recognises the need for ‘almost complete decarbonization of the power sector’ (Storm, 2011: 410), it continues to fund vast coal-fired power stations and puts its faith in questionable scenarios of hugescale economical carbon-capture-and storage, bio-fuels production, and so on. Yet ‘half of the energy models reviewed in the [WD] Report conclude that the required de-carbonization (before 2050) is technologically infeasible (at acceptable costs, whatever that may mean)’ (loc. cit.). The WDR emphasises the urgency of investment in adaptation in LDCs. This covers ‘changing the kinds of risks people prepare for; where they live; what they eat; and the way they design, develop, and manage agroecological and urban systems’ (WDR p.10). The HDR goes somewhat further. Given its diagnosis of the problem in terms of impacts on human rights and human development, it identifies relevant responses differently and more broadly. ‘Successful adaptation policies cannot be grafted on to systems 20 that are failing to address underlying causes of poverty, vulnerability and wider disparities’ (p.27 [15]). It insists that HIEs are morally ‘obliged to support adaptation capacity development’ (p.25 [14]), and brings in the threat of LDCs responding to damage by invoking ‘the legal principles of protection from harm and compensation for damage’ (p.25 [14]). It is outspoken about the ‘derisory’ response (p.25 [14]) so far by rich countries to help poor countries adapt to damage caused by the rich; and insists on the rich’s obligation to provide ‘new and additional’ support for adaptation, not divert other aid (p.26 [15]). 5.4. Mobilisation and orchestration of the proximate means -technology and finances – via a multilateral mechanism North-to-South transfer of technologies and finance, for both mitigation and adaptation, is a major topic in both reports. The WDR discusses it at special length, perhaps reflecting Bank ambitions to coordinate the transfers. It uses repeatedly the notion of a ‘global deal’ between high-income and developing countries: the WDR Overview employs the term ‘deal’ (as a noun) sixteen times, as in ‘global deal’; the HDR Overview not at all. Forester (2009) remarks that the conception of bargaining a ‘deal’ rests on a picture of given fixed identities and purposes, and can obscure many opportunities and dangers. The WDR ‘deal’ includes, first, international transfers of clean technologies, cost-sharing agreements, and financial support for the incremental cost of adopting new technologies. Second, pricing carbon through taxes or cap-and-trade will generate finance, though most finance required for infrastructure will come via the private sector (WDR p. 24). Third, the public sector must create incentives for climate action, flexibly regulate private infrastructure service providers, supply information and education, and eliminate market failures. Fourth, a system for financing and administration of the deal. Additionally, says the WDR, the deal must be acceptable for highincome countries, which means their competitiveness must not suffer, especially in relation to middle income countries (p.22). The HDR too strongly advocates financial and technology transfers (p.23 [13]), but it frames the issues in terms of responsibility and social justice (p.28 [16]), and does not refer to maintaining HIE competitiveness. For pricing carbon in HIEs, via carbon taxes and/or cap-and-trade mechanisms to generate finance, it takes the same line as the WDR. Both reports advocate a planned, controlled and orchestrated process of action in LDCs. Who will plan, control and orchestrate? Both reports see a multilateral mechanism as ideal to manage the transfers from HIEs to LDCs. Various statements in the WDR suggest the Bank’s wish to position itself centre-stage in climate funds management, which is ‘no trivial matter’ (p.2). It stresses the expertise needed, how ‘action must be enabled by an efficient and 21 effective international agreement, one that factors in development realities’ (p.19), and how 'the aid experience does offer critical lessons’ (p.22), including the need for centralization rather than having innumerable funders. It hints thus at a new ‘deal’ for the World Bank too, the self-styled ‘knowledge bank’. In contrast, the HDR argues that: ‘While project-based support has an important role to play, the locus for adaptation planning has to be shifted towards national programmes and budgets’ (p.27 [15]). 5.5 Market mechanisms Both Reports emphasize the role of markets to raise finance and re-incentivize activity. According to the HDR’s Foreword, price mechanisms should be used instead of quotas (p.5 [vii]); and ‘putting a price on carbon emissions [is] the starting point’ (HDR p.20 [10]), which can be done through either a carbon tax or cap-and-trade. The HDR seems not to mind which, and its final list of recommendations includes suggestions for both options (p.29 [17]). The reports agree that a global carbon market is a long-term project. In the short run the markets will not be global, because ‘the world lacks the required governance system’ (HDR p.20 [11]). The HDR proposes ‘rich countries [should] develop carbon pricing structures [and] [a]s these structures evolve, developing countries could be integrated over time as institutional conditions allow’ (HDR p.20 [11]). The WDR gives a similar discussion in later chapters. The HDR recognises that ‘market pricing alone will not be enough’ for carbon (p.13 [5]), given the numerous forms of market failure seen in carbon trading. Governments must set regulatory standards and support low-carbon R&D and deployment (HDR p.21 [11]). Although the influence of power groups in the determination of the caps for emissions is acknowledged in the Report, Opschoor complains that its ‘analysis remains superficial. So does the discussion on the flaws of [the Clean Development Mechanism]’ (2008: 132). Both Reports incline towards open global product markets. The HDR’s mitigation strategy includes expansion of alternative fuels markets, such as for ethanol, where tropical countries may have comparative advantage (HDR, p.22 [12]). The WDR argues the same (p.308) and advocates open markets in general. ‘To ensure adequate water and nutrition for all, the world will have to rely on an improved trade system less prone to large price shifts’ (p.14). ‘Improved’ is equated to more open and global, on the grounds that more integrated world markets will allow LDCs access to rich country markets when LDCs have surpluses, and will reduce local price fluctuations. But integrated markets allow food to be moved out to areas of higher purchasing power, away from poor people, and they allow food crops to be displaced by more lucrative production for global markets on land from which poor people have been displaced. Storm (2011) comments on the WDR’s lack of discussion of the 22 interests of ‘rural landless workers, the urban poor and the non-agricultural workers’ as food prices rise (p.409), and on the assumptions that markets in poor countries will generate the historically unprecedented required agricultural productivity rises as climate deteriorates and populations rise. ‘The discrepancy between “required” yield growth and “likely yield growth with moderate warming” is huge in the developing world, but rather small in the rich regions…[Further,] The principal uncertainties in the estimates are all on the downside’ (Storm p.409). The WDR focuses on an area that is considered much less in the HDR: changes in the management of energy supply, agricultural practices, water and other resources in LDCs. To cut GHG emissions in LDCs without sacrificing growth, the WDR advocates higher fuel taxes and reduction of energy subsidies (pp.14-15). In contrast, it says nothing in the Overview about energy prices, subsidies and taxes in high-income economies, such as the USA. The pricing measures in LDCs should be accompanied, according to the WDR, by other tools for advancing energy efficiency, such as norms, regulatory reform and financial incentives that attract private power companies. Such reforms are not scheduled for the North because rich countries are supposedly ready for adapting without help, both reports imply. Proposals to further privatize energy supply would leave national states with less control and capacity to manage shocks related to energy. Control over energy production would probably lie in the hands of international investors. The opening of LDC markets can bring greater control over resources in LDCs by powerful market actors, funding agencies and, indirectly, rich country governments. The HDR says far less on systems for the management of resources in LDCs, but the multilateral mechanisms that it envisages might similarly open the door for this in weaker economies. 6 Two ways of approaching the future? The structured comparison of the problem-framing and solution-framing in the two Reports, supported by attention to key vocabulary, has given us many insights beyond those in earlier review essays such as by Opschoor (2008) and Storm (2011) who do not analyse the texts systematically or comparatively. Similarly, we go significantly beyond Flottum and Dahl (2012) who compare linguistic content but do not extend this into a frame analysis in terms of issues from the literatures on climate change, policy analysis and international development organisations. We suggest two major findings. First, the HDR 2007/8 and the WDR 2010 represent importantly different perspectives on the problem of climate change in relation to lowincome people. For the Human Development Report the problem is a fundamental civilizational issue, in which the basic life quality and even 23 sometimes the lives of poor people--‘rural communities in Bangladesh, farmers in Ethiopia and slum dwellers in Haiti’ (p.10 [3])--are endangered, in large degree by actions by others, in rich countries, who thus have a compelling moral obligation to provide support and to modify their current patterns of living. The HDR makes frequent use of terms and phrases like ‘the world’ (including as an actor, such as ‘If the world acts now…’; p.10 [3]), ‘humanity’, ‘the world’s poor’, ‘the international community’, ‘human community’, ‘our children’, ‘our children and grandchildren’, ‘future generations’, ‘the world’s poor and future generations’. None of this language characterises the World Development Report (see Table 2). Its Overview never mentions grandchildren or future generations, and rarely employs even the pronoun ‘we’, the indicator of shared fate and shared concern and commitment. Its favoured terms are ‘manage’ and ‘efficiency’. The contrast of vocabularies shown in the table is stark and revealing. Beyond the local messages conveyed by choices of terms, we have looked for the overall messages embodied in patterns of argumentation (van Dijk 2009). Section 4 compared the main problem specifications across the two Overviews, and Section 5 did so for their policy designs. We saw important differences between the two Reports in framing the problem space, differences that have implications for the framing of the solutions space and the choice of policy options. The WDR evinces less urgency, which reflects its greater concern with monetary magnitudes and hence implicitly with the interests of those with more resources to protect themselves from possible future stresses. The HDR’s reliance on a currency of human welfare highlights that lives can be broken and stunted, and contributes to its greater sense of urgency and willingness to query unending economic growth in rich countries. These differences are substantive, though the Reports also share ideas about inertia and possible lock-in, which can, together with a standard market-based conceptualisation of ‘efficiency’, direct attention primarily towards influencing the faster-growing LDCs rather than to major changes in high-income countries. 24 TABLE 2 Vocabularies of the Overview chapters in HDR 2007/8 and WDR 20101 We Children our children Grandchildren future generations the world’s poor and future generations the world’s poor the poor [as a noun; in addition to uses of ‘the world’s poor’] the world Human Humanity community/communities the international community global community human community 56 (29) 11 (3) 4 (2) 3 (1) 19 (0) 6 (0) 17 (0) 12 (0) 11 [2] 3 0 0 0 0 0 1 [1] 32 (8) 102 (19) 8 (0) 11 (2) 2 (1) 1 (0) 2 (0) 13 [6] 8 [2] 1 9 1 0 0 climate smart efficiency/efficient/inefficient/inefficiency Effective 0 (0) 21 (1) 2 9 48 (4) 12 Consumption threshold/s catastrophe/s/catastrophic ‘window of opportunity’ insurance/ insurers/ insure climate insurance precaution / precautionary 7 (0) 7 (0) 13 (2) 3 (0) 3 (3) 0 (0) 1 (0) 19 (0) 1 [1] 7 [2] 0 16 [2] 5 1 Fight 5 (4) 1 challenge/s Can manage/(mis)management/mismanaging 27 (6) 32 (3) 6 (0) 10 [2] 77 (3) 26 [8] The HDR Overview is electronically available as a file that includes front matter and the Foreword, itself an important statement that functions as close partner to the Overview. Table 1 distinguishes word-occurrences in the HDR Overview and the Foreword/Contents (the latter occurrences are given in round brackets.) Their sum (plus occurrences in the front matter) gives the total count for the downloadable file. The WDR 2010’s Foreword is far less significant, only a third the length of the HDR’s, and is functionally distinct and presented in a separate file. The main word counts in Table 1 for the WDR Overview exclude its References section, since the HDR Overview has no References; counts in square brackets concern the References. 1 25 Our second major finding is that, compared to their significantly different diagnoses of the problem space, the two reports are surprisingly similar in major policy proposals. They largely share a technocratic, market-based programme: a carbon price in rich countries, which will help to finance a global insurance system of efficient mitigation measures and prudent adaptation measures in poorer countries and support the growth that those countries need; a multilateral mechanism for conditional, expert, program-based planning and disbursement of the support; which together with an increased reliance on global markets will imply greater control by powerful global actors over LDC economies, combined with a lack of multilateral enforcement mechanisms for rich countries. There are also differences: the HDR calls for carbon budgets for all countries and more program flexibility for LDCs, and is explicit about the ethical underpinnings—solidarity over time and obligations of rich countries arising from the damage to others that they are responsible for—which together imply (but here the HDR hesitates) limits to further economic growth in rich countries; whereas the WDR tries to proceed with only a language of self-interest and win-win ‘deals’, with little or no talk of Northern obligations or self-limitation, let alone of human rights. Yet the bulk of the proposals are the same. Following its stress on human rights and ethical principles, the HDR does relatively little to apply those ideas in policy proposals (Opschoor, 2008: 1201). It takes for granted that its proposals are compatible with the intrinsic value of human beings and their rights, though market mechanisms are only suitable where it is possible and appropriate to price things (and people). It does little to query existing climate policy mechanisms as potentially negative to vulnerable people; to articulate possible creative new solutions driven by local actors; and to use existing policy frameworks, laws and norms and other UN specialized agencies to convert its framing of the problems into a framing of actions. Such proposals were present in the HDR 2000 on the relations between human development and human rights (UNDP 2000). The 2000 Report was a more consistent document, outlining policy options for development work aligned with human rights principles and the constitutional rights established in many countries. Whether the key constraints were the training of HDR 2007/8’s team in economics schools in the North, its modest budget compared to the World Bank’s research resources, political pressures within and upon a multilateral agency in a global political environment resistant to address the challenges that climate change poses to growth driven development models, or even other factors, would require a separate study to try to answer. Fault lines may be sensed between the HDR’s Foreword, co-written by Kemal Dervis, the UNDP Administrator, who had spent a quarter-century in the World Bank, and its Overview, led by Kevin Watkins, who had spent much of his career in Oxfam, 26 which espouses a rights-based approach. The Foreword, while steeped in ‘We’ language, insists on the priority of market solutions (p.5 [vii]). The HDR 2007/8 seems a classic UN report, influenced by inspiring humanist perspectives but with lesser resources for research than the WDR and little associated funding for programs with which to induce others to accept its ideas. It was perhaps then led to propose a synthetic set of practical measures that did not offend potential funders and largely relied on proposals worked out by richer agencies. In contrast, the WDR represents a working-out of a mainstream economic vision of a world smoothly ordered by corporations and markets, and is marked by convenient omissions and techno-optimism wherever required for maintaining this vision (Storm, 2011) and by absence of reflection regarding the models of development that have led to the climate crises. In the WDR’s organizational and intellectual context, climate change and poverty are technical problems to be addressed by economic policy and technological innovation, led by the development aid bureaucracies and global business. The problems will be resolved, not intensified, by economic growth. Societies become judged then according to their aggregate consumption achievements, more than by the way they treat their most vulnerable members; and marketbased ‘solutions’ are put forward to whatever difficulties may arise, such as climate change (O’Brien et al. 2010; St.Clair, 2009). ‘Economic growth alone is unlikely to be fast or equitable enough to counter threats from climate change’ acknowledges the WDR in one of its summary ‘Main Messages’, but this can supposedly be compensated for by the carbon-pricing and multilateral-guided programs for mitigation and adaptation that the Report outlines. As climate impacts become more visible and a global agreement on mitigation measures remains elusive, and as research investigating current policy options for climate solutions unveils serious failures and even negative impacts on the poor and vulnerable, the analysis presented here tells us much of relevance for the role of multilateral institutions in the current debate on climate change and development. The structuralist belief in ‘lock-in’ already in the North, and fear of an imminent high-carbon ‘lock-in’ too in the South, led the HDR 2007/8 to share the mainstream focus on change of direction in the South rather than the North. Its belief in ‘the fierce urgency of the now’ rushed the HDR to a full policy package designed in terms of various instruments already available on the tables of its member-state governments. Yet those instruments may not respond well to the basic ethical and human rights concerns that HDR 2007/8 had forcefully articulated. While support is building for critical views such as expressed in the HDR 2007/8 (Books, Grist and Brown 2009; Lohman, 2006, Marino and Ribot 2012, 2011; Storm ed. 2009), the failure to convert its critique far into a distinctive policy approach shows how development multilaterals can become locked in the dominant 27 dichotomy between North and South and ineffective in unsettling unsustainable and unjust models of development. The United Nations Intellectual History Project (1999-2010) concluded that to achieve practical impact a movement of ideas needs an intellectual vision, consistent with and partnered by an inspiring set of values; and further, that these two must become action-relevant by being operationalised in actionagendas and methodologies and practical proposals, and institutionalised in organizations, processes and networks that carry the ideas forward and continually press for their use (Jolly, Emmerij, Weiss, 2009). The HDR 2007/8 may have fallen short in its network of active cooperators, and especially (and consequently) in conversion of its vision and values into practical means rather than taking over means that have been devised to express different visions and values. By implication, a new Human Development Report on climate change would be appropriate, whether by UNDP or others, to go further with that conversion, on the basis of insights from a broader network and perhaps a different process of knowledge production, possibly more akin to that of the IPCC. The inconsistency shown by HDR 2007/8 may also indicate more than weakness in a single report. It could suggest that thinking about new policy options to address the ethical and human rights challenges raised by climate change requires more distance from existing power structures, rather than closeness. Perhaps besides agency Reports, new process models need consideration, such as globally coordinated assessments of available thinking, along the lines of the IPCC assessment procedures. Acknowledgement: Our thanks go to Trine Dahl, Kjersti Fløttum, Desmond McNeill, Kevin Watkins, three anonymous referees, and participants in seminars in The Hague, Durban and Oslo for valuable reactions and suggestions. 28 References Alexander, R.J., 2009. Framing Discourse on the Environment: A Critical Discourse Approach. Routledge, London, Antaki, C., Billig, M., Edwards, D., & Potter, J., 2003. Discourse Analysis Means Doing Analysis: A Critique of Six Analytic Shortcomings. Discourse Analysis Online, 1(1). http://extra.shu.ac.uk/daol/articles/v1/n1/a1/antaki2002002.html Barnett, J., O’Neill, S., 2010. Maladaptation. Global Environmental Change 20, 211– 213. de Boer, J.; Waardekker, J.A.; van der Sluijs, J., 2010. Frame-based guide to situated decision-making on climate change. Global Environmental Change, 20, 501510. Books, N. Grist, N. and Brown, K., 2009. Development futures in the context of climate change: Challenging the present and learning from the past. Development Policy Review 27 (6), 741-765. Broad, R.,., 2006. Research, knowledge, and the art of “paradigm maintenance”: The World Bank’s Development Economics Vice-Presidency (DEC). Review of International Political Economy, 13(3), 387–419. Broad, R., 2007. Knowledge management: A case study of the World Bank’s Research Department. Development in Practice 17(4), 700-708. Graig, D. and Porter, D., 2006. Development Beyond Neoliberalism?: Governance, Poverty Reduction and Political Economy. Routledge: New York and London. Fløttum, K., Dahl, T. 2012. Different contexts, different "stories"? A linguistic comparison of two development reports on climate change. Language & Communication 32, 14-23. Goffman, E., 1974. Frame Analysis: An essay on the organization of experience. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Goldman. M. 2005. Imperial Nature : The World Bank Struggles for Social Justice in the Age of Globalization. New Haven and London: Yale University Press Heltberg, R., Siegel, P.B., and Jorgensen S.L., 2009. Addressing human vulnerability to climate change: Toward a ‘no-regrets’ approach. Global Environmental Change 9(1), 89-99. IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change), 2007. Fourth Assessment Report. http://www.ipcc.ch/ and Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. IPCC, 2012. Managing the Risks of Extreme Events and Disasters to Advance Climate Change Adaptation. http://www.ipcc-wg2.gov/SREX/ Jolly, R., L. Emmerij, T.G. Weiss, 2009. UN Ideas that Changed the World. Indiana University Press. Kahneman, D., Tversky, A., 1984. Choices, values, and frames. American Psychologist 39(4): 341-350. Kanbur, R., 2001. Economic Policy, Distribution and Poverty: The Nature of Disagreements. World Development, 29(6), 1083–1094. Lakoff, G., 2001. Moral Politics: How Liberals and Conservatives Think. University of Chicago Press. Lawson, V. 2009. Reshaping Economic Geography? Producing Spaces of Inclusive 29 Development. NACLA Report on the Americas 86(4), 351-360. Lohman, L., 2006. Carbon Trading. Development Dialogue 48, 1-359. Lohman, L. , 2011. Capital and climate change. Development and Change 42(2), 649– 668. Marino, E. and J. Ribot, 2012. Adding insult to injury: Climate change and the inequities of climate intervention. Global Environmental Change 22(2), 323328. Mawdsley, E. and J. Riggs, 2003. The World Development Report II: continuity and change in development orthodoxies. Progress in Development Studies 3(4), 271-286. McMichael, P., 2009. Banking on Agriculture: A Review of the World Development Report 2008. Journal of Agrarian Change 9(2), 235–246. McNeill, D. and St.Clair, A.L., 2009. Global Poverty, Ethics and Human Rights: The Role of Multilateral Organisations. Routledge, London. McNeill, D. and St.Clair, A.L., 2011. The World Bank's expertise: Observant participation in the World Development Report 2006, Equity and Development. In Mosse, D. (ed.) Adventures in Aidland: The Anthropology of Professionals in International Development. Berham Books, London, pp. 3-22. Mosse, D., 2011. ed. Adventures in Aidland: The Anthropology of Professionals in International Development. Berham Books, London. Murphy, C., 2006. The United Nations Development Programme: A Better Way? Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, Mass. O’Brien, K., St.Clair A.L. and Kristoffersen, B., 2010. The framing of climate change: why it matters. In O’Brien, K., St.Clair, A.L., and Kristoffersen, B. (eds.) Climate Change, Ethics and Human Security, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, p. 3-22. Opschoor, J.B., 2008. Fighting Climate Change – Human Solidarity in a Divided World. Development and Change 39(6), 1193-1202. Rigg, J.; A. Bebbington, K Gough, D Bryceson, J Agergaard, N Fold, C Tacoli, 2009. The World Development Report 2009 ‘reshapes economic geography’: geographical reflections. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 34(2), 128-136. Schmidt, R., 2006. Value-Critical Policy Analysis. In D. Yanow & P. Schwartz-Shea (eds.,) Interpretation and Method. M.E. Sharpe, Armonk, NY, pp.300-315. Schön, D., and Rein, M., 1994. Frame Reflection: Towards the Resolution of Intractable Policy Controversies. New York, Basic Books. St.Clair, A.L., 2006a. Global poverty: The co-production of knowledge and politics. Global Social Policy 6(1), 57-77. St.Clair, A.L. , 2006b. The World Bank as an transnational expert institution. Global Governance 12(1), 77-96. St. Clair, A. L., 2010. Global poverty and climate change: Towards the responsibility to protect. In O’Brien, K., St.Clair, A.L., and Kristoffersen, B. (eds.), Climate Change, Ethics and Human Security. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. 180-198. 30 Stern, N., 2007. The Economics of Climate Change – The Stern Review. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Stern, N., 2010. A Blueprint For A Safer Planet - How We Can Save the World and Create Prosperity. Vintage Books, London. Stone. D. 2012. Governance via Knowledge: Actors, Institutions and Networks. In D. Levi-Faur (Ed): Oxford Handbook of Governance. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 339-353. Stone, D. and Wright, C. (Eds.), 2006, The World Bank and governance: A decade of reform and reaction. Routledge, London. Storm, S., ed., 2009. Capitalism and Climate Change. Development and Change 40(6). Storm, S., 2011. WDR 2010: The World Bank’s Micawberish agenda for development in a climate-constrained world. Development and Change 42(1), 399-418. The Independent, 2009. Climate scientists – it´s time for plan B. http://www.independent.co.uk/environment/climate-change/climatescientists-its-time-for-plan-b-1221092.html UNDP, 2000. Human Development Report 2000. UNDP, New York. UNDP, 2007. Human Development Report 2007/8 - Fighting Climate Change – Human Solidarity in a Divided World. UNDP and Palgrave Macmillan, New York. UNIHP. United Nations Intellectual History Project. http://www.unhistory.org/publications/ van Dijk, T., 2009. Critical Discourse Studies: A Sociocognitive Approach. In: Wodak, R.; Meyer, M. (Eds.): Methods of Critical Discourse Analysis, second edition, Sage, London: pp.62-86. Wade, R., 1996. Japan, the World Bank, and the art of paradigm maintenance: The East Asian miracle in perspective. New Left Review 217: 3-36. Wade. R, 2001. Making the World Development Report 2000: Attacking Poverty. World Development 19(8): 1435-1441. Wade, R., 2002. US hegemony and the World Bank: The fight over people and ideas. Review of International Political Economy 9(2), 215–43. Wodak, R., 2008. Discourse Studies: important concepts and terms. In Wodak, R., & Krzyzanowski, M. (eds), 2008. Qualitative Discourse Analysis in The Social Sciences. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke: pp.1-20. World Bank, 2008. Development and Climate Change: A Strategic Framework for the World Bank Group, http://beta.worldbank.org/overview/strategicframework-development-and-climate-change accessed 15 June 2011. World Bank, 2009. World Development Report 2010: Development and Climate Change. World Bank, Washington DC. Yanow, D., 2000. Conducting Interpretive Policy Analysis. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA. 31